University of Denver University of Denver
Digital Commons @ DU Digital Commons @ DU
Electronic Theses and Dissertations Graduate Studies
2023
Free Trade is Not Free: A Case for Fair Trade Free Trade is Not Free: A Case for Fair Trade
Wardah Javaid Cheema
University of Denver
Follow this and additional works at: https://digitalcommons.du.edu/etd
Part of the International Economics Commons
Recommended Citation Recommended Citation
Cheema, Wardah Javaid, "Free Trade is Not Free: A Case for Fair Trade" (2023).
Electronic Theses and
Dissertations
. 2246.
https://digitalcommons.du.edu/etd/2246
This Thesis is brought to you for free and open access by the Graduate Studies at Digital Commons @ DU. It has
been accepted for inclusion in Electronic Theses and Dissertations by an authorized administrator of Digital
Commons @ DU. For more information, please contact jennifer[email protected],[email protected].
Free Trade is Not Free: A Case for Fair Trade Free Trade is Not Free: A Case for Fair Trade
Abstract Abstract
To this day, mainstream economists favor free trade policies as the best way to generate economic
development. They do so at the expense of their unjusti?ed romanticization of reductionist classical trade
theories. This thesis seeks to comprehend the constraints of traditional trade theories and their inability
to be applied to practical contemporary problems. Further, contrary to the fundamental assumption of
free trade theory, there is ample evidence of government intervention in free trade agreements. These
interventions solely encourage and protect large corporations and investors rather than the actual
development and sustainability factors, namely labor and the environment. It all adds up to a compelling
case for developing and implementing a fair trade regime.
Document Type Document Type
Thesis
Degree Name Degree Name
M.A.
Department Department
Economics
First Advisor First Advisor
Chiara Piovani
Second Advisor Second Advisor
Robert G. Urquhart
Third Advisor Third Advisor
Henning Schwardt
Keywords Keywords
Environmental standards, Fair trade, Free trade, Free trade agreements, Labor standards
Subject Categories Subject Categories
Economics | International Economics | Social and Behavioral Sciences
Publication Statement Publication Statement
Copyright is held by the author. User is responsible for all copyright compliance.
This thesis is available at Digital Commons @ DU: https://digitalcommons.du.edu/etd/2246
Free Trade is Not Free: A Case for Fair Trade
______________
A Thesis
Presented to
the Faculty of the College of Arts, Humanities and Social Sciences
University of Denver
____________
In Partial Fulfillment
of the Requirements for the Degree
Master of Arts
____________
by
Wardah Javaid Cheema
June 2023
Advisor: Dr. Chiara Piovani
©Copyright by Wardah Javaid Cheema 2023
All Rights Reserved
ii
Author: Wardah Javaid Cheema
Title: Free Trade is Not Free: A Case for Fair Trade
Advisor: Dr. Chiara Piovani
Degree Date: June 2023
Abstract
To this day, mainstream economists favor free trade policies as the best way to
generate economic development. They do so at the expense of their unjustified
romanticization of reductionist classical trade theories. This thesis seeks to comprehend
the constraints of traditional trade theories and their inability to be applied to practical
contemporary problems. Further, contrary to the fundamental assumption of free trade
theory, there is ample evidence of government intervention in free trade agreements. These
interventions solely encourage and protect large corporations and investors rather than the
actual development and sustainability factors, namely labor and the environment. It all adds
up to a compelling case for developing and implementing a fair trade regime.
iii
Acknowledgements
First and foremost, I would like to express my gratitude to my parents for their
unending love, unwavering faith in me, and constant encouragement. Their
steadfast support, sacrifices, and dedication to my education have been the bedrock of my
success. I am eternally grateful for the values they instilled in me and the opportunities
they provided me. I would also like to express heartfelt gratitude towards my dear brother’s
endless support, belief in my abilities, and encouragement that inspired me to achieve my
best. Furthermore, I am extremely thankful to my wonderful husband’s wise advice,
motivation to push my boundaries and for being a rock of strength for me throughout this
journey.
I would especially like to express profound appreciation to my supervisor, Dr.
Chiara Piovani, for her invaluable guidance and mentorship. Her expertise, constructive
feedback, and constant support have been instrumental in shaping this thesis. I am deeply
grateful for her dedication and commitment to my academic and personal growth this past
year. Thank you for teaching me the art of being humble and wise.
Moreover, I am grateful for Dr. Markus Schneider, who has been my mentor
throughout and has encouraged me greatly since the beginning of my master’s degree. I
am thankful to Dr. George DeMartino for his insightful guidance and valuable
contributions to my research. His expertise and scholarly advice have greatly influenced
the direction of my work. I am grateful for his eagerness to share his knowledge and his
genuine interest in my academic development. I would also like to extend my sincere
gratitude to Dr. Robert Urquhart for his wisdoms that have been vital in shaping my
research. Thank you all for being incredible teachers and mentors.
iv
Table of Contents
Chapter 1: Introduction .................................................................................................... 1
Chapter 2: Fair Trade: Historical and Conceptual Introduction ................................. 6
2.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................... 6
2.2 Historical Background and Context .......................................................................... 7
2.3 Understanding Fair Trade: Theoretical Frameworks .............................................. 12
2.3.1. Amartya Sen’s Capability Approach ............................................................... 12
2.3.2. Marxist Economic Approach .......................................................................... 20
2.4 Fair Trade Policy Proposals .................................................................................... 30
2.5.1. The Social Charter Approach .......................................................................... 30
2.5.2. The Social Tariff Approach ............................................................................. 33
2.5.3. The Sullivan Principles Approach ................................................................... 38
2.6 Conclusion ............................................................................................................... 40
Chapter 3: A Brief History of International Trade Theories and their Impact on
Globalization .................................................................................................................... 43
3.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................. 43
3.2 Theoretical Limitations of International Trade Theories ........................................ 45
3.2.1. Mercantilism .................................................................................................... 45
3.2.2. Classical Economic Theory: ............................................................................ 49
3.2.3. Neo-classical Economic Theory ...................................................................... 55
3.2.4. New Trade Theory .......................................................................................... 59
3.3. A Critical Reassessment of Trade Models ............................................................. 62
3.3.1. Historical Evidence Against Old Trade Theories ........................................... 62
3.3.2. Deepening of globalization: Redefining Role of Government ........................ 64
3.3. Impacts of Trade Liberalization and Hyper Globalization ..................................... 71
3.3.1. Ecological Imbalances: Competing on Environmental Standards .................. 72
3.3.2. Social Imbalances: Competing on Labor Standards and Safety ..................... 75
3.5 Conclusion ............................................................................................................... 79
Chapter 4: How Free Are "FTAs"? Evidence of Government Intervention ............ 81
4.1 Introduction ............................................................................................................. 81
4.2 Brief History of North American Free Trade Agreements ..................................... 82
4.3 Government Intervention in Provisions of the Free Trade Agreements ................. 86
4.3.1. Intellectual Property Rights (IPRs) ................................................................. 86
4.3.2. Investor-State Dispute Settlement (ISDS) ....................................................... 90
v
4.3.3. Government Procurement (GP) ....................................................................... 92
4.3.4 Regulatory Cooperation ................................................................................... 95
4.3.5. Anticorruption Provisions ............................................................................... 96
4.3.6. Social and Ecological Provisions .................................................................... 99
4.4. Conclusion ............................................................................................................ 101
Chapter 5: Conclusion .................................................................................................. 104
References ...................................................................................................................... 109
vi
List of Abbreviations
ANC African National Congress
CA Comparative Advantage
CAFTA-DR Central America-Dominican Republic Free Trade Agreement
FDI Foreign Direct Investment
FTA Free Trade Agreements
GATT Global Agreement on Tariffs and Trade
GDP Gross Domestic Product
GHGs Greenhouse Gases
GP Government Procurement
HDI Human Development Index
HDR Human Development Report
IMF International Monetary Fund
IPCC Intergovernmental Panel on Climate Change
IPR Intellectual Property Rights
ISDS Investor-State Dispute Settlement
ITO International Trade Organization
KORUS-FTA US-Korea Free Trade Agreement
LDC Less Developed Countries
NAFTA North American Free Trade Agreement
NGOs Non-governmental Organizations
OAS Organization of American States
OECD Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development
PTPA Pacific Trade Pact Agreement
PWC Post-Washington Consensus
QC Quality Control
SITS Social Index Tariff Structure
TPP Trans-Pacific Partnership.
TRIMs Trade-Related Investment Measures
TRIPS Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Right
UNDP United Nations Development Program
USMCA United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement
USTR United States Trade Representative
WB World Bank
WC Washington Consensus
WTO World Trade Organization
1
Chapter 1: Introduction
Since the beginning of the 1980s, the economic performance of individual nations
has become increasingly dependent on the dynamics of the global economy. This brought
to light trade as the most conspicuous and contentious policy space, where the advent of
global neoliberalism has been disputed in recent years. The international community has
been advocating for neoliberal policies such as free trade, which are being implemented in
both developed and developing countries. This has been predominantly driven by the belief
that free trade is the primary engine of economic expansion and progress. As a result, state-
imposed tariffs of any kind on international trade flows have been considered inefficient
and almost completely hindering the progress of developing nations in the economic world.
Further, the World Bank (WB), World Trade Organization (WTO), and International
Monetary Fund (IMF) have also constituted the influence or interreference of any state in
international trade as inefficient and causing market distortions. This thesis aims to
investigate the fundamental concerns associated with free trade that make it not truly "free".
The inclusion of provisions safeguarding intellectual property rights and mandating the
enforcement of stringent copyright laws in free trade agreements has been observed to
result in increased expenses for consumers and potential constraints on innovation and
competition. Accordingly, the objective is to analyze the extent to which fair trade provides
a morally and environmentally responsible substitute for global trade.
2
Chapter 2 primarily focuses on the background of fair trade policy and proposals.
It explores the background, context, and relevance of the fair trade proposals that we are
proposing as the solution to mitigate the negative impacts of neoliberalism throughout the
world. Under the relevant context of fair trade theory, the chapter will shed light on the
need for and emergence of fair trade theory in practice. It will further analyze the
conceptual framework behind the fair trade theory. The capabilities equality approach
proposed by Sen and Marxist economic theory are employed as the most viable conceptual
frameworks for the implementation of fair trade, given their emphasis on the promotion of
human welfare and the equitable allocation of resources. The aforementioned frameworks
facilitate the adoption of equitable labor regulations and environmental preservation in fair
trade methodologies, which are indispensable for ensuring sustainable and ethical
commerce. Fair labor standards emphasize the protection of workers' rights, such as
equitable compensation, safe working conditions, and the capacity to form unions. This is
consistent with the principles of Marxist ideology, which places emphasis on the
importance of providing fair remuneration for work. The capabilities approach
acknowledges the significance of the well-being and growth of workers in enhancing their
capacities and empowering their agency. The significance of ecological conservation in
fair trade lies in its promotion of sustainable and responsible practices aimed at reducing
environmental damage. The Marxist theoretical framework acknowledges the
interdependence between economic structures and the natural environment, whereas the
capabilities approach prioritizes the conservation of the ecological system for the
betterment of present and future cohorts.
3
This thesis centers on the proposition that governments ought to implement
rigorous labor and environmental regulations. Consequently, the viewpoints of Amartya
Sen and Karl Marx are subjected to critical scrutiny. The latter portion of the chapter delves
into an analysis of three discrete policy alternatives for fair trade, along with their
respective methodologies for implementing an equitable trading system. Advocates of fair
trade have been promoting various aspects of social, economic, and ecological
development for a considerable period of time with the intention of raising awareness about
these issues. However, the assessment of each proposal on an individual basis falls beyond
the purview of this research.
The adherence of numerous mainstream economists to the notion that free trade is
the sole strategy capable of driving the growth and development of nations and economies
can be attributed to their unfounded idealization of the reductionist methodology employed
in classical and neoclassical trade theories. A meticulous examination of the existing body
of literature pertaining to the constraints of conventional trade models was conducted in
Chapter 3 of this thesis to undertake supplementary analysis. First, it presents a brief
description of the theoretical frameworks of classical, neo-classical, and new trade theories
by assessing the contributions made by the theories of absolute advantage by Smith,
comparative advantage by Ricardo and Heckscher-Ohlin-Samuelson, and economies of
scale by Paul Krugman, respectively. What follows is an examination of the implications
of conventional trade theory by comparing and contrasting it with fair trade frameworks.
After that, it examines their flaws and limitations, which make them inappropriate and
inadequate for grasping international commerce and growth within the framework of the
4
present global economy. The next section provides a detailed criticism of classical and neo-
classical theories as they were extensively used to advocate for "free trade" as the ultimate
trade theory for mutual growth and development. Chang’s extensive criticism of developed
countries hypocritically preaches to developing countries to adopt liberal trade policies for
growth and development. In reference to the new trade theory, Paul Krugman’s redefining
of the role of government in trade policies is analytically analyzed to understand the impact
and repercussions of hyper globalization.
In light of this, Chapter 4 provides detailed evidence of government intervention in
free trade. The chapter demarcates that certain free trade agreements (FTAs) include
provisions that protect particular industries or countries, which fundamentally goes against
the primary principles of free trade. It examines various free trade agreements (FTAs) that
incorporate patent and copyright provisions, which confer benefits on large corporations
while potentially disadvantaging small businesses and developing nations. Furthermore, it
analyzes how FTAs possess the capability to lead to employment reductions in industries
that lack competitiveness. The chapter substantiates the critique of FTAs by asserting that
they deviate from the tenets of unrestricted trade by providing safeguards to particular
enterprises or nations. It presents evidence of various provisions restricting trade and
competition in several FTAs signed by the United States. It attempts to understand how the
inclusion of these provisions has the potential to provide benefits to specific businesses or
nations but may also impede the principles of unrestricted commerce. The chapter also
analyzes the sustainability of the inclusion of provisions incorporating ecological and
social regulations to create a level playing field for all signatories.
5
Chapter 5 provides conclusive remarks on the discourse surrounding international
trade policy. The author arrives at a precise conclusion, advocating for the establishment
of a state-led fair trade system, which is supported by two distinct lines of reasoning. The
limitations and inaccuracies of theories supporting free trade suggest that the underlying
theoretical framework is flawed. Consequently, those mainstream economists who
continue to advocate for fully liberalized trade may be doing so out of obstinacy. The
economists in question have not adequately anticipated the rapid transition from
globalization to hyper globalization and have also neglected to account for the significance
of human rights and ecological preservation. The second strand of the argument centers on
the evidence indicating that the concept of "free trade," which is promoted and executed
through the signing of Free Trade Agreements (FTAs), has not truly been free. The
available evidence regarding the involvement of the state in the development of these free
trade agreements (FTAs) establishes a robust framework for the role of government in
shaping trade policies. The state is currently perceived to be operating in a manner that
favors large corporations, while global financial institutions, such as the World Trade
Organization, have been observed to operate in a manner that favors the global north. The
argument put forth by fair traders advocating for the implementation of labor standards to
reinforce social justice and environmental standards for the purpose of ecological
conservation is a sound one.
6
Chapter 2: Fair Trade: Historical and Conceptual Introduction
2.1 Introduction
The current chapter provides an overview of the historical context of fair trade and
the diverse perspectives that have been discussed regarding the establishment of ethical
and sustainable international trade practices. It will indulge in historical background of fair
trade movement, the specific context relevant to our study, and fair trade policies and
practices under organized purview. The chapter begins with an introduction of the fair
traders advocating for the states to mediate trade flows according to strong executable
standards regarding sustainable environmental practices, human and labor rights, gender
equality, eradication of child labor. It first, briefly, gives an uneasy historical development
of trade policies in the United States. The United State switch from protectionist policies
to free trade is analyzed. Many mainstream economists preach the world to adopt free trade
policies if they want to see growth in their economy. However, the history as evident
through research by many heterodox economists provides the intel that the countries that
are now developed and preaching trade liberalization are the ones who industrialized and
developed by adopting a rather strategic trade policy, which mostly was protectionist
policies to protect their infant industries in their early years struggling for development.
The chapter also clarifies the context under which this thesis attempts to advocate for fair
trade policies. A critical approach that necessitates the role of government in establishing
fair trade policies is the context this thesis advocates for fair trade.
7
The chapter then goes on to provide theoretical frameworks, Marx’s Economic
Theory and Amartya Sen’s capabilities equality approach, for understanding the socio-
economics importance of fair trade regime. Since the major focus of this thesis is on
inclusion of strict labor and environmental standards by the governments, the evidence
supporting importance of these two have been reviewed and analyzed in the writings of
Amartya Sen and Karl Marx. The last section of the chapter provides three different types
of fair trade policy proposals and their methodologies to implement a fair trade regime.
The proposals have been included to understand the aspects of social, economic, and
ecological development that the fair traders have long been championing for. Therefore,
the individual critical analysis of these proposals is beyond the scope of this research.
2.2 Historical Background and Context
'Fair trade,' or new trade and investment regimes that may enjoy the advantages of
international economic integration while shielding disadvantaged communities from the
most harmful tendencies of neo-liberalism, emerged in the 1990s. It was highly advocated
by heterodox economists and social movements around the world. Neoclassical trade
theorists, in reaction to the free traders, reaffirmed their support for free trade throughout
the 1990s and beyond, and even urged for additional liberalization (DeMartino, 2019).
This, first of all, points us towards understanding the long and complicated history of free
trade in the United, with policies and tactics changing throughout time in response to
changes in economic, political, and social conditions. Free trade and protectionist measures
have both been enacted at various points in U.S. history, with both having been pushed for
8
by different governments, political parties, and interest groups. The United States has
maintained its free trade and protectionist policy mix throughout the last several decades
despite shifting its economic and political objectives after industrializing. Since the
repercussions of hyper globalization, a byproduct of trade liberalization, have started to be
widely experienced, trade imbalances, labor and environmental standards, intellectual
property rights, and the effects of globalization on domestic companies and employees
have all been the subject of heated discussion and controversy.
Conversely, there was also a concerted campaign in the 1990s to build a global
system of "fair trade," driven by a broad mix of activists and academics who adhered to
non-mainstream economic ideas. Fair trade advocates used the new trade and investment
initiatives of the time, such as the negotiations for the Global Agreement on Tariffs and
Trade (GATT), which resulted in the World Trade Organization (WTO), and the North
American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), to incorporate strong, enforceable standards
concerning labor and human rights, child labor exploitation, gender equality in
employment, and environmental practices. These guidelines were patterned after the
GATT talks that culminated in the World Trade Organization (DeMartino, 2014). Fair
trade supporters have said that global economic integration promoted profits and growth
by increasing worker exploitation, the wealth gap, and environmental degradation. It has
been seen over and again that free trade and foreign direct investments harmed (or
obstructed the execution of) social safeguards in countries that already had strong
safeguards in place, and that they hindered the development of such safeguards in nations
that already had poor safeguards in place.
9
In recent decades, "fair trade" has been a popular term among academics, socially
aware corporations, international development professionals, social movement activists,
and morally concerned consumers. Raynolds and Bennett (2015) describes:
“As a concept, fair trade refers to a critique of the historical
inequalities inherent in international trade and to a belief that
trade can be made more socially just. This notion is
increasingly linked to a set of concrete initiatives that
challenge global inequalities and create more egalitarian
commodity networks, linking marginalized producers in the
global South with progressive consumers in the global
North. In moving from abstract concept to grounded
practice, fair trade works to transform international trade
from a vehicle of exploitation to an avenue of empowerment.
In the global South, fair trade seeks to enhance wellbeing
by fostering higher prices and wages, stable markets and
employment, better work conditions and environmental
sustainability and to bolster individual and collective
capacities – by strengthening information exchanges, social
service access, opportunities for self-determination and local
organizations. In the global North, fair trade seeks to bolster
more equitable trade policies, business models and
consumption practices by making available a range of goods
that are produced under more socially just and
environmentally sustainable conditions.” (p. 3)
World Fair Trade Organization (WFTO) declares that the fair trade movement
originated when people realized that traditional trading methods were harmful to both
society and the environment. The late 1940s and early 1950s are seen as the beginning of
the debate over fair trade since it was during this era that talks and campaigns for more
equitable trading practices gained traction. The year 1988 was a watershed moment in the
growth of the fair trade movement since it saw the establishment of the first Fair Trade
Organization, a Dutch organization known as "Max Havelaar." This meeting marked the
start of a coordinated campaign to promote fair trade norms in the agriculture and food
10
industries. Each of these company’s value fair trade practices. The Max Havelaar label was
created to help ensure that small-scale farmers in developing nations were paid a living
wage for the things they produced and had access to resources that would enable them to
better their communities. A diverse range of stakeholders, including consumers, producers,
governments, non-governmental organizations (NGOs), and international organizations,
have been involved in the fair trade debate from its inception. As a result of continual
discussions, debates, and activities related to fair trade principles, practices, and
consequences, the movement has grown in relevance and awareness in the global economy.
According to Lyon (2010), the present fair trade movement is based on a significant
and developing contradiction. When faced with escalating poverty and environmental
damage in many developing nations, many buyers of fair trade products are motivated by
a fierce opposition to the effects of neoliberal globalization. Fair trade, on the other hand,
seeks a market-based solution to the issues posed by free markets to promote social justice
and environmental sustainability (Lyon, 2010). The World Bank has advocated for market-
based fair trade as an alternative to government-enforced labor standards and commodity
control schemes, and a recent observer observed that fair trade's "voluntarist, non-statist
program has been viewed by public institutions and corporations as fundamentally
compatible with neoliberal reforms" (Fridell, 2007).
In a rather contemporary approach, fair trade promotes social justice by embracing
deregulated markets, which are often responsible for deepening poverty in rural regions,
rather than legal and legislative solutions enacted by governments on behalf of farmers and
workers living inside their borders. Consequently, fair trade is often co-opted by the same
corporations against which it formerly battled (Lyon, 2010), since its methods of attaining
11
social justice are constrained by the nature of modern markets and the entities that regulate
them. In short, Fair trade aims to change North/South commerce from a tool of exploitation
to one of empowerment by challenging historically unfair international market relations.
via a "trade, not aid" approach, Fair Trade seeks to reduce poverty in the developing world
by bolstering producer groups and communities and enhancing the economic security of
farmers and workers via more sales at fair prices.
This thesis, however, explicitly examines a critical and progressive approach on
fair trade, which includes the state to practice its autonomy and legislate to take, what fair
traders’ reason are the basic social rights such as: labor standards, environmental standards,
gender-based discrimination, out of competition to impede the exploitation based on
comparative advantage in global trade. The motivation behind adopting this particular
progressive and radical fair trade approach, as opposed to the market based fair trade
marked goods approach, is predicated on the inherent tendency of markets to fail.
1
The free
market mechanism may not result in the most efficient distribution of resources or may not
produce favorable outcomes for the broader community. When market failures occur, it
may be necessary to implement government intervention or other corrective measures in
order to attain more efficient outcomes or address social objectives. Therefore, this thesis
employs the role of government to establish fair trade regimes as suited for ta nation in
accordance with overcoming the critical harms explicated by DeMartino (2000) under free
trade:
“When wages, hours and work intensity are removed
from competition, the sweating of labor ceases to be a
1
Market failure is a phenomenon that occurs when the distribution of goods and services in an unregulated
market fails to attain an optimal result.
12
viable innovation; when consumer safety laws are
effectively implemented, the adulteration of input
materials becomes unavailable in pursuit of competitive
advantage; when strict environmental standards are
enforced, new profitable technologies that increase
external social costs (e.g., pollution) while reducing
private costs are eclipsed by other technologies that
reduce social costs.” (p. 188)
2.3 Understanding Fair Trade: Theoretical Frameworks
This section establishes relevance of two important economic ideas to the doctrine
of fair trade. Fair trade methodologies play a crucial role in promoting sustainable and
ethical trade by facilitating the adoption of equitable labor regulations and environmental
preservation practices. The fair labor standards prioritize safeguarding the entitlements of
laborers, including fair remuneration, secure working environments, and the ability to
establish labor unions. The aforementioned statement aligns with the fundamental tenets
of the two theories examined in the following sections. In short, these two theories are
reasonable compliments to the fair trade theory itself.
2.3.1. Amartya Sen’s Capability Approach
Sen's capabilities equality approach provides a strong conceptual foundation for
fair trade by essentially highlighting the importance of human well-being, individual
capabilities, and social justice. A primary goal of the concept known as "fair trade" is to
foster more equitable and ecologically responsible economic operations, particularly with
respect to less developed countries and producers on the market's periphery. Sen's
capabilities approach is consistent with the goals and ideas underpinning fair trade in a
number of fundamental ways. The capability approach places human well-being at the
center of development, emphasizing the importance of people's capabilities or freedoms to
13
live a life they value. Human well-being is central to this approach to development.
Similarly, fair trade prioritizes the well-being of producers, workers, and communities. Its
fundamental purpose is to provide opportunities for these groups' long-term economic
development and social improvement. Nussbaum (2000), wholeheartedly agreeing with
Sen writes:
“Sen’s primary use of the notion of capability is to indicate
a space within which comparisons of quality of life (or, as
he sometimes says, standard of living) are most fruitfully
made. Instead of asking about people’s satisfactions, or how
much in the way of resources they are able to command, we
ask, instead, about what they are actually able to do or to be.
Sen has also insisted that it is in the space of capabilities that
questions about social equality and inequality are best
raised.” (p. 12)
When compared to traditional economic frameworks for analyzing poverty,
inequality, and human development, Sen's capability approach has emerged as the most
popular option in the recent decade (Clarke, 2006). Sen's criticisms of conventional welfare
economics provide the theoretical underpinnings for the capabilities equalities approach
(Sen, 1999). Conventional welfare economics tends to confuse well-being with either
opulence-commodities or utility-happiness (Crocker, 1992). Clark (2006) outlines how
Aristotle, Classical Political Economy, and Karl Marx all contributed to the development
of the capabilities approach. Marxist economic theory is also adopted in this thesis to
provide another theoretical framework for fair trade.
Fair trade is an alternative strategy suggested by Sen's internationalist definition of
capabilities equality, that is, the convergence of capacities at an appropriate, generally
accessible, and long-term level (DeMartino, 2000). DeMartino (2000) in his book sets that:
14
“The import of capabilities equality in the trade debate is to
provide a compelling basis for rejecting neoclassical
theory’s strict agnosticism regarding the sources of
comparative advantage. The principle encourages us to
interrogate the strategies that nations (and indeed,
communities and firms) adopt in pursuit of their economic
interests, and to adjudicate what should and what should not
serve as sources of comparative advantage…nations should
be allowed (and indeed encouraged) to adopt strategies that
promote capabilities equality and should be barred from
undertaking those strategies that interfere with this end.
From the capabilities perspective, then, we are likely to
conclude that gender discrimination in employment or weak
worker health and safety standards do not qualify as
legitimate policies. Global policy regimes should therefore
disallow (or counter the effects of) such strategies in the
formation of comparative advantage.” (p. 208)
The capability approach prioritizes addressing social inequities such as economic
inequity, discrimination, and exclusion. This is because the method realizes that in order
to be successful, social justice must be prioritized. Fair trade strives to eliminate the global
economic gaps that exist between various groups of people by encouraging fairer trading
practices such as paying fair prices to producers, permitting market access, and promoting
social and environmental sustainability.
The capabilities approach emphasizes the need of prioritizing the capabilities of
society's most vulnerable and disadvantaged groups, such as women, children, and the
poor. This shows compassion for disadvantaged populations. Similarly, fair trade
prioritizes the rights and well-being of underprivileged producers, workers, and
communities in order to empower these people and communities and increase social
inclusion. Furthermore, it accentuates the importance of sustainable development, which
is development that is holistic in character and considers social, economic, and
15
environmental elements of development. Fair trade attempts to support sustainable
production and consumption practices, such as organic farming, fair pay, and
environmentally friendly production processes, in order to ensure the long-term well-being
of producers, workers, and the environment. Not only this, but the capabilities equality
approach also recognizes the importance of ethical issues in the formulation of
development policies and practices. These concerns may include issues of democratic
government, social justice, and human rights. Similarly, ethical issues are integrated into
commercial methods and relationships via fair trade. Fostering transparency,
accountability, and participatory decision-making are among the ethical factors.
Sen's capability approach, in general, provides a theoretical foundation for fair
trade. Since it prioritizes human well-being, social justice, sustainability, ethical concerns,
and the empowerment of underprivileged producers and employees, therefore, its ideals
and ideas are compatible with fair trade. This approach highly stresses the need of
addressing social and economic inequalities, since these imbalances have the potential to
limit people's capacities and freedoms. Due of its focus on competitive markets and profit
maximization, free trade has the potential to exacerbate disparities by providing strong
nations or firms an edge over economies that are less developed or smaller. As a
consequence, rewards and opportunities are distributed unevenly (Sen, 1999).
The capabilities approach, as proposed by Amartya Sen, is a theoretical construct
that offers a more comprehensive outlook on human welfare and progress, surpassing
conventional metrics such as financial resources or economic advancement. The
capabilities approach prioritizes agency and freedom, highlighting the significance of an
individual's capabilities to lead a life of personal value and to exercise autonomy in making
16
choices that promote their overall welfare. Moreover, it places significant importance on
the development of human potential, encompassing a diverse set of skills and abilities that
are essential for individuals to achieve a sense of personal satisfaction and underscores the
significance of tackling social disparities and advocating for social equity. The capabilities
approach prioritizes a comprehensive assessment of well-being that is sensitive to the
contextual factors that shape the social, cultural, and economic realities of individuals.
The fair trade regime aims to achieve a harmonious equilibrium between policy
autonomy and universal commitments/rules
2
. The fair trade approach aims to impose
specific constraints on policy autonomy, such as prohibiting the utilization of child labor
and prison labor. However, it simultaneously aims to maintain policy autonomy regarding
the methods employed by each nation to accomplish the objectives outlined in the fair trade
system. This thesis will attempt to emphasize on inclusion of fair labor and environmental
rights are also strongly complemented by the capability approach, since Sen’s theory
emphasizes the need of decent work and fair labor conditions as necessary components of
human happiness. Further it will emphasize on the need for achieving a balance between
policy autonomy and universal commitments to labor, human, and environmental
protections as imperative.
Free trade may result in a "race to the bottom" in labor standards as countries
compete for investment and trade by reducing worker protections, cutting worker costs,
and undermining worker rights. This may result in employee exploitation, the
2
Since several neo-classical economists support the notion of free trade by arguing that governments ought
to possess extensive autonomy in labor and environmental policy. They contend that comparative
advantage, which is based on varying labor and environmental standards, can be justified by cultural
relativism.
17
establishment of dreadful working conditions, and the violation of basic labor rights,
particularly in less developed countries (Ghosh, 2015). Additionally, the capability
approach recognizes the importance of environmental sustainability to human well-being,
both now and in future generations, and emphasizes this component of human flourishing.
With its emphasis on economic growth and the unrestricted movement of goods and
services, free trade can lead to environmental degradation, natural resource depletion, and
pollution, all of which contribute to climate change and undermine the capabilities of
vulnerable communities, particularly those in developing countries (Martinez-Alier, 2002).
Since there has been excessive disagreement on the idea of having universal labor
and environmental laws, the capabilities equalities approach provides a significance of
local autonomy and self-determination in the process of building culturally acceptable
development routes that are responsive to local needs and values. When countries are
forced to conform to global trade laws and regulations that may not correspond to their
local values, cultures, or priorities, free trade may result in the loss of local autonomy. This
is due to the fact that nations are required to comply with global trade laws and regulations
(Nussbaum, 2000). The capabilities equality approach emphasizes the need of establishing
democratic governance and participatory decision-making when developing development
strategies and objectives. Consequently, power is concentrated. Free trade agreements,
which are typically negotiated between strong governments or businesses, may concentrate
power in the hands of a few and undermine democratic governance, resulting to the
exclusion and limitation of disadvantaged groups. FTAs are often negotiated between
strong nations or enterprises (Lustig et al., 2010).
18
Many neoliberal proponents fail to see that free trade doctrine puts the market,
rather than the state, in charge of meeting social, environmental, and monetary
commitments (Edelman and Haugerud, 2005)
3
. Contrary to that, numerous advocates of
fair trade say that the "free market" terminology utilized by governments in developed
countries is essentially disingenuous. They observe that these governments utilize global
institutions such as the IMF and WTO to compel subsidy elimination in developing
countries while retaining protectionist policies in their own economy (Stiglitz 2002).
Therefore, governments in the industrialized North dump a major amount of their surpluses
at cheap prices on deregulated markets in the global South, much to the disgust of local
farmers (Fridell, 2007).
4
The capabilities approach, as we have seen, proposes that the enhancement of
human capacities, rather than economic growth, should serve as the primary goal of
development. While expansion is often crucial to progress, it is not always enough. Dreze
and Sen (1989) and Sen (1999) outline two major categories of development: growth-
mediated and support-led. The former is put into action through quick and widespread
economic development, which paves the way for an increase in fundamental capacities via
more employment, greater income, and enhanced social services. The latter is effective
because of well-designed social programs that promote health, education, and security. In
times of disaster and suffering, public action plays a vital role in both directly supporting
capacities and increasing political pressure for governmental involvement (Clark, 2006).
3
This is also a fundamental rationale for advocating a more progressive and radical stance on fair trade as
opposed to the certification-based fair trade model that operates within the framework of the free market.
4
This happens because the North subsidizes its agricultural sectors by an estimated billion dollars per day.
19
The CA can be widened by including agency, which acknowledges that people have values
and goals (like protecting the environment, buying free trade products, or fighting injustice,
tyranny, and oppression) that go beyond and, at times, even contradict individual
happiness. Inequality, social justice, living standards, and rights and responsibilities are
now focal points in the capabilities approach (Clark, 2006).
The capability approach, developed by Amartya Sen and Martha Nussbaum,
emphasizes the importance of human capabilities and well-being. DeMartino (2000)
reasons that for fair trade to have the potential to develop skills and well-being, it must
ensure that people are paid fairly, and that environmental sustainability is recognized. In
this context, "capabilities equality" refers to the idea that everyone should have equal
access to the capabilities needed to live a happy life, such as educational and medical
opportunities, as well as economic chances. According to the capabilities approach,
developed by economist and philosopher Amartya Sen, real equality can be achieved only
when everyone has equal access to specific talents, rather than just equal access to
resources. True equality can only be achieved in this manner. Fair trade, on the other hand,
is a commercial practice that assures farmers and other employees in developing countries
are paid a salary commensurate with the worth of the items they create. This business model
was created in order to make international trade more equal. Fair trade principles often
involve paying producers fair rates, providing employees with safe and healthy working
conditions, and contributing to the prosperity of local communities.
In a nutshell, there is a clear relationship between capabilities equality and fair
trade. We can increase the likelihood that people in developing countries will have access
to the opportunities and resources they need to live a meaningful life if we fight to
20
strengthen fair trade practices. This includes sufficient remuneration for their work, access
to educational opportunities and training, and the ability to participate in decision-making
at the local level. By striving to promote equality in capabilities, we can contribute to
ensure that all individuals, regardless of where they live or what resources they have, have
the opportunity to live lives that are significant to them.
2.3.2. Marxist Economic Approach
The framework and concept of fair trade also correspondences with Marxist
Economic approach. Many heterodox economists contends that Marx's ideas are still
relevant today (McGonnigal, 2012; Eagleton and Mosquera, 2011; Hudson and Hudson,
2003; Webb 2007; Geysmans and Hustinx, 2016; Nilsen, 2020). Marx's ideas are more
pertinent now than they have ever been, particularly in the dispute between those who
support free trade and those who support fair trade. It is widely observed that hyper
globalization is one of the most critical challenges that the global economy at the present
time is prone to face. Therefore, as fair traders are advocating for stern solutions to this
problem, we need to refer to Marx's very convincing indictment of capitalism (Hudson and
Hudson, 2003; Webb 2007; Geysmans and Hustinx, 2016; Nilsen, 2020). Hence, it is safe
to conclude that distresses, such as labor exploitation and environmental degradation,
stemming from capitalism, as evident by Marx’s writings, are significantly what the fair
traders are concerned for. Marx in Capital Volume I, demarcates that:
“Capitalist production, therefore, only develops the techniques
and the degree of combination of the social process of
production by simultaneously undermining the original sources
of all wealth the soil and the worker.” (p. 638)
21
This thesis explores exploitation of cheap labor and poor environmental standards
out of many problematic outcomes of globalization. Numerous academic disciplines,
including economics, politics, sociology, history, and anthropology, have conducted
research on the idea of exploitation, each arriving at a somewhat different theoretical
framework as a result (Berger-Tal, 2014; Sindzingre, 2018). Because of its centrality in
Marx's works, the Marxist ideas and disputes around the notion have become de facto
canonical texts for future examinations of the subject (Sindzingre, 2018). The idea of
exploitation, as well as the question of what exactly constitutes exploitation and how it
should be defined, has been the topic of driven contentions in the trade debate. However,
unfortunately, for whatever reason, exploitation has always been considered nothing more
than a simple reality (Krugman, 1997); nonetheless, it is also a notion that needs critical
reexamination.
According to neoclassical economic theory, exploitation occurs when a producer
gets paid less than the marginal output of a given production factor (Hodgson, 1980), and
therefore, to maximize the returns the trade should take place based on comparative
advantage (Ricardo, 1817). Marx's view, on the other hand, is that workers are exploited
whenever they generate surplus value above what they are paid for it. This is because
capitalists use coercion over the labor process to appropriate this surplus value (Sindzingre,
2018). To Marxist point of view, exploitation refers to the process through which workers
hand over their economic surplus to capitalists. Yoshihara (2017) delineates that one of the
chief characteristics of exploitation in a capitalist system is the unequal exchange of labor
among workers. This explicitly resonates with the aim of fair traders to advocate for fair
labor standards for all laborers, in both developed and developing countries.
22
To understand Marxist Economics as a framework for fair trade, first we need to
understand his commodity fetishism. Personifying objects and economic classifications are
what Marx defines as "commodity fetishism" (Marx, 1887; Hudson and Hudson, 2003).
Anything that can be witnessed when the part of social connections that overshadows
individuals, manifests themselves externally as domination by specific items is the
objectification of production relations between people under the circumstances of
commodity production based on private ownership (Hudson and Hudson, 2003). The
capitalist personifies capital as a production relation, whereas the worker represents wage
labor. The exploitation of man by man, which is hidden by the payment of wages, is only
one illustration of the pervasive fetishism that penetrates all economic categories of
capitalist society. Commodity fetishism reaches its pinnacle when one becomes obsessed
with accumulating wealth and material possessions (Marx, 1887).
Marxist economic theory critiques the concentration of power in the hands of
multinational corporations under capitalism. In his book Capital: Critique of Political
Economy, Marx elaborates on the process by which people go from being passive holders
of money (capital) to active capitalists who put others to work for profit (1867). As Marx
puts it, "dead labor" is put to use by "living labor," or workers, to create new value. Marx
considers the physical means of production to be a source of value since they are utilized
by workers and are the result of the activity of previous workers. There are two points of
argument he raises. He begins by saying that employees add value to the physical means
of production by using them. Even while it adds to the economy, labor is nonetheless
abused. In a fascinating phrase at the end of chapter six, Marx in Capital Volume 1,
envisions a stylized exchange between the "owner of money" and the "owner of this
23
peculiar commodity, labor-power," who meet in a marketplace to trade their respective
possessions. They get together as equals in order to do this transaction, but then:
“On leaving this sphere of simple circulation or of exchange
of commodities, which furnishes the “Free-trader Vulgaris”
with his views and ideas, and with the standard by which he
judges a society based on capital and wages, we think we can
perceive a change in the physiognomy of our dramatis
personae. He, who before was the money-owner, now strides
in front as capitalist; the possessor of labor-power follows as
his laborer. The one with an air of importance, smirking,
intent on business; the other, timid and holding back, like
one who is bringing his own hide to market and has nothing
to expect but — a hiding.” (p. 280)
This thesis attempts to understand how the closest form of Marx's ideal society can
be achieved by implementing fair trade initiatives and understand the essential problems
rooted within David Ricardo's theory of comparative advantage and specialization which
is seen as the most straight and basic definition of free trade (Ricardo, 1817). Under a free
trade regime, restrictions like tariffs, quotas, and sanctions are not in place, and to
maximize output while minimizing input costs, it emphasizes a cost-benefit analysis of
manufacturing only. However, Marxist ideas like reliance and exploitation can be traced
back to the fair trade doctrine (Eisenberg 2005).
To improve trading circumstances, fair trade primarily aims to strengthen
cooperation, conversation, transparency, and respect. To ensure that mass productions,
especially factories producing on FDIs, produce under conditions of no child labor,
environmental sustainability, strict labor standards, and various regulations to ensure
worker safety, fair trade advocates work to encourage states to practice policy autonomy
and establish their own ideal labor and environmental standards (Fridell, 2006). In a
24
nutshell, the major objective of fair trade policies is to enhance working conditions for the
sake of worker safety and the reduction of other unfavorable consequences of globalization.
According to Eagleton (2015), this means that "decisions on the overall allocation of
resources" would be set by representative assemblies at the local, regional, and national
levels, and that "an economy which would be neither centrally planned nor market
governed" will serve as a shorthand for the Marxist vision.
In light of this, this thesis evaluates fair trade as a model of 21st-century Marxist
economics in international commerce. Since Marx's criticism is congruent with the
problems that fair trade seeks to solve, the Marxist economic approach is utilized as the
basis for the fair trade approach in this thesis. Marx postulated a vision of societal
alterations and a phase of metamorphosis towards improvement. He held the belief that the
ultimate goal ought to be the overthrow of capitalism and the establishment of a socialist
community. Nevertheless, the implementation of reforms that tackle the fundamental social
challenges is necessary to achieve this objective. Marx posited that the elimination of
capitalism required a revolutionary struggle by the proletariat, aimed at obtaining dominion
over the means of production and establishing communal ownership. Marx's critique of
capitalism centered on the exploitation of laborers and the inequitable distribution of
wealth. In a similar vein, the fair trade movement attempts to tackle issues of exploitation
by advocating for trading practices that are more just and balanced, as well as regulations
that promote fair labor and environmental standards, and mechanisms for ensuring
accountability.
Holland (2015) argues that the concept of comparative advantage, which originated
with Ricardo, is a flawed basis for economic policy because it assumes immobility of
25
capital while, in reality, FDI has been the primary force behind the expansion of
international trade since World War II and the confirmation of Marx's claims of unequal
development. He explains that this has led to unequal results, undermining the Bretton
Woods system established after World War II, and he proposes a post-Ricardian and post-
Keynesian conceptual framework for global government, which this thesis argues may
fundamentally be a system of free and equitable commerce. Marxist economic theory
emphasizes the exploitation of labor under capitalism - a bigger canopy to put neo-
liberalism under (Marx, 1877; Eisenberg, 2005), where workers are often subjected to poor
working conditions, low wages, and exploitation by employers. Which again points
towards the immediate and effective inclusion of labor laws in trade agreements, such as
those related to minimum wages, working hours, and workplace safety, to help protect the
rights and well-being of workers. By promoting fair labor standards, trade agreements can
help address exploitation in global supply chains, ensure that workers are treated fairly,
and prevent a race to the bottom where countries compete by lowering labor standards to
attract investment (Gitterman, 2003; Burgoon and Hiscox, 2000; Drezner 2001; Van den
Putte and Orbie 2015). This perfectly aligns with Marxist critique of exploitation which
contributes to more equitable and just labor associations in international trade.
Further, Marxist economic theory also emphasizes the importance of workers'
rights and collective bargaining power in challenging the power imbalances between labor
and capital. Marx also argues “that unions and strikes were a vital means to militate against
exploitation and wage the class struggle against capitalists” (Hampton, 2008). Labor laws
in trade agreements can help promote workers' rights, such as the right to organize, bargain
collectively, and engage in peaceful strikes (Kim and Park 2014). By empowering workers
26
to have a voice in their working conditions and wages, labor laws in trade agreements can
help rebalance power dynamics in global supply chains and promote more democratic and
participatory workplaces (Dorman, 1988). This brings into line Marx’s emphasis on the
role of collective action in advancing workers' interests and can contribute again to more
equitable and inclusive labor relations. Marxist economic theory critiques the social
inequalities generated by capitalism, including wealth concentration and income
disparities. Labor laws in trade agreements can include provisions that promote equitable
distribution of economic benefits, such as requirements for fair wages, gender and racial
equality, and social protection measures (Dorman, 1988). By addressing social inequality,
labor laws in trade agreements can help promote social justice, reduce disparities, and
contribute to more inclusive and equitable societies which has also been Marx’s staunch
emphasis on addressing inequality in economic systems, and can therefore, contribute to
more just and balanced trade relationships globally.
Marxist economic theory, like fair trade, recognizes the environmental impact of
capitalism as well, including environmental degradation, resource extraction, and climate
change (Foster, 2014). Environmental laws in trade agreements can include provisions that
promote environmental sustainability, such as requirements for environmental standards,
conservation measures, and sustainable resource management. Promoting environmentally
responsible production and trade practices, environmental laws in trade agreements can
help protect the environment, prevent ecological harm, and contribute to sustainable
development (Esty, 2001; Runge, 1994; Rodrik, 1997; Summers, 2000). This aligns with
Marxist recognition of the interdependence between economic systems and the
27
environment and can contribute to more sustainable and responsible trade relationships
(Burkett, 2006).
Fair trade activists have helped radicalize and grow ecological defense groups
around the globe as globalization's effects on the environment have deteriorated. This has
led many scholars to return to Marx in search of more holistic, dialectical explanations of
the social degradation of the environment (Foster, 2015; Foster and Holleman, 2014). To
such an extent that it is embedded in the very framework of Marx's value analysis (Burkett,
2006), the alienation of nature is a central part of Marx's criticism of political economy
and, by extension, of capital. He also underlined that people were a part of nature and the
inherent conflict between their use value and their trade worth. Marx and Engles
characterize the work and production process as a component of the "universal metabolic
process" (Marx and Engles, 1861–1863, p. 63). Marx described socialism as the "rational
regulation by associated producers of the metabolism between humanity and nature,"
(Burkett, 2006). Marx argued that no one, not even all the people on Earth, owned the
planet, but rather that they only possessed it in usufruct as "good heads of the household,"
and that they owed it to future generations to pass it on in better form than they had
inherited it. (Marx, 1894 : 911, 959). For instance, Marx argued that "Man lives on nature—
means that nature is his body, with which he must remain in continuous interchange if he
is not to die" (Economic and Philosophical Manuscripts, 1844) in order to explain how
humans depend on the natural world. Because man is a part of nature, the fact that nature
is essential to his bodily and spiritual well-being is equivalent to saying that nature is
essential to itself. Marx (1873) explains that:
28
“It is not the unity of living and active humanity with the
natural, inorganic conditions of their metabolic exchange
with nature, and hence their appropriation of nature, that
requires explanation or is the result of a historic process, but
rather the separation between these inorganic conditions of
human existence and this active existence, a separation
which is complete.” (p. 489)
The sustainable development aspects of shared resources, co-evolution, and
common property are all accounted for in Marx and Engels' communist approach. In
addition, this perspective integrates environmental and social scientific approaches in a
manner that is both practical and intellectual, which is in keeping with the multidisciplinary
nature of ecological economics (Burkett, 2006).
According to Burkett (2006), the rising global revolt against dominant economic
institutions (transnational businesses, the IMF, the WB, and the WTO) is driven by the
need for more egalitarian and ecologically sustainable living options, which this thesis
attempts to prove is a worldwide fair trade regime. The market, private profit, and other
kinds of exploitation and oppression are not the driving forces behind human growth, he
argues, and this movement requires a framework for the discussion, reconciliation, and
implementation of alternative human development methods driven by life values.
If this interpretation is right, then environmentalists' (fair traders) ultimate goal
must be the eradication of capitalism rather than incremental reforms inside it. We need to
build a society based on collaboration, economic democracy, and long-term sustainability
to prevent ecological disaster (Gasper, 2013).
In Capital, Volume 3, Marx lays forth his vision for such a society:
“From the standpoint of a higher socio-economic
formation, the private property of particular individuals in
29
the earth will appear just as absurd as the private property
of one man in other men.
Even an entire society, a nation or all simultaneously
existing societies taken together are not owners of the earth,
they are simply its possessors, its beneficiaries, and have to
bequeath it in an improved state to succeeding generations,
as boni patres familias [good heads of households].” (p.
911)
Their most in-depth examination of this issue was found in Marx's Speech on the Question
of Free Trade, which was presented in Brussels in January 1848, just before to the
publication of the Communist Manifesto (Hampton, 2008). In response to the question of
“what is free trade under the present condition of society?”, Marx (1848) makes the
argument that:
"When you have overthrown the few national barriers which
still restrict the progress of capital, you will merely have
given it complete freedom of action. So long as you let the
relation of wage labor to capital exist, it does not matter how
favorable the conditions under which the exchange of
commodities takes place, there will always be a class which
will exploit and a class which will be exploited. It is really
difficult to understand the claim of the free traders who
imagine that the more advantageous application of capital
will abolish the antagonism between industrial capitalists
and wage workers. On the contrary, the only result will be
that the antagonism of these two classes will stand out still
more clearly.” (para. 1)
In his criticism of capitalism, Marx addresses a variety of topics, including political
impotence as a result of capitalism, the exploitation of the worker class, income inequities,
and more (Eagleton 2011). Labor and environmental laws in trade agreements can help
challenge corporate power by regulating the activities of corporations in global supply
chains, setting standards for their operations, and holding them accountable for their social
30
and environmental impacts (Chapman and Suri, 1998; French 1993). By promoting
transparency, accountability, and responsible business conduct, labor and environmental
laws in trade agreements can help prevent corporate abuses, promote corporate social
responsibility, and contribute to more balanced and accountable trade relationships. This
aligns with Marxist critique of corporate power and can contribute to more equitable and
just global economic governance (Gasper, 2013).
2.4 Fair Trade Policy Proposals
Fair trade presents an alternative approach to international trade, with the aim of
promoting ethical and sustainable practices. The emergence of the fair trade concept was a
direct response to the exploitation of workers and small-scale producers in developing
nations by multinational corporations that prioritize financial gain over the welfare of
individuals and the environment. Various fair trade initiatives provide a set of viable
solutions to tackle the aforementioned concerns through the promotion of equitable
remuneration, secure labor conditions, and ecological preservation. It is important to note
that these proposals have their own limitations. The discussion about their limitations is
beyond the scope of this study but nevertheless important.
2.5.1. The Social Charter Approach
The social charter is a widely supported strategy for accomplishing the objective of
setting up a fair trade regime. If a country wants to join a single market, it must sign on to
a social charter promising to maintain a certain baseline of social protections. These rights,
which may be seen as reflecting what member states consider to be valuable functions, are
established via multilateral discussions among the concerned States. As a result, the charter
31
might be seen as laying forth minimum standards for competence in the single market.
Proponents argue that if a country has a strong enough charter, it will not engage in immoral
actions in order to gain a competitive edge. Europe is the birthplace of the modern social
charter movement.
Several North American fair traders, inspired by the European approach, which was
included in the 1992 European integration talks, fought unsuccessfully to get a social
charter included in NAFTA. The Charter guarantees a wide range of rights, from those in
the workplace to those of children, the old, and the handicapped (Kraw 1990). For instance,
Brown et al., noted that the draft charter included steps to strengthen the social safety net
and boost community and worker participation in upholding basic environmental and labor
norms (1992).
In 1993, Rothstein debriefed about the international labor laws and international
trade that:
“The Clinton administration has many opportunities to
expand American export markets in the Third World, as
well as to protect U.S. jobs from unfair low-wage
competition, by a policy which gives greater emphasis to
internationally recognized labor standards. The policy must
be guided by a new international development strategy
which recognizes that higher wages and the creation of
internal markets are as important to Third World
development as export opportunities.” (p. 31)
Although the final, agreed-upon Charter falls well short of its proponents' hopes,
certain (limited) social and labor norms are standardized throughout Europe (Silvia 1991).
Hence, the social charters are there to help regular people and solve their concerns and as
a result provide a level playing field for all the economic stakeholders, specially the labor.
32
Hence, modern trade agreements must adopt a cooperative strategy that prioritizes
capacity-building and fosters active citizen participation, with civil society in each country
guaranteed the legal standing to bring instances within the context of a renegotiated
agreement (Castaeda and Heredia 1992).
The basic premises behind each of the NAFTA parallel track institutions are
important for charting the course of future trade and environment efforts, even if the
specific structures and functions of the NAFTA parallel track institutions are perhaps best
suited to the particular circumstances of the NAFTA. Important lessons for future trade
and environment efforts can be learned from NAFTA's Environmental Provisions. The
implementation of these laws, together with the successes and failures that occur as a result,
will serve as an important laboratory for nurturing solutions to many trade and
environmental concerns. We can no longer treat trade agreements like NAFTA as if they
were corporate bill of rights (Castafieda and Heredia 1992).
Our national governments are jeopardizing our ability to meet urgent ecological
concerns because they do not fully understand or effectively address the environmental
implications of current trade agreements. This was found to be the case by (Shrybman
1992) that to pacify the fair-traders in Congress, the Clinton administration negotiated two
side agreements to NAFTA on worker rights and environmental preservation. While all
three signatories must adopt their own labor and environmental rules, it is vital to remember
that the side agreements do not impose a unified standard across the continent (Hufbauer
and Schott, 1993). There are many promising aspects to the social charter approach, but it
also has some significant weaknesses.
33
2.5.2. The Social Tariff Approach
Alternatively, "social tariffs", a unilateral approach, could be applied to products
made in countries with less robust labor and environmental protections. The objective of
this strategy is to prevent the loss of progress made in nations with high standards of labor
and environmental protection while simultaneously encouraging the adoption of such
standards in countries with lower ones. It aims for this by eliminating the benefit that
enterprises with lower standards over their competitors have (Lebowitz 1988). There could
be a number of benefits to implementing an environmental tariff in order to create a more
equitable trading system (Chapman 1991). He further elaborate that the funds raised could
be used to finance pollution control in developing countries, some part of the tariff funds
could be allocated for research on the general problems of transnational externalities and
world pollution, and producer resistance to pollution control would be diminished.
Environmental protection groups in developing nations would have a stronger
domestic political position with the help of a social tariff. Further, businesses that invest in
cutting-edge pollution-prevention technology would benefit economically. Due to the
minimal possibility of low-standard countries agreeing to multilateral accords that contain
a social tariff, a properly structured tariff would be levied unilaterally by the high-standard
country (Dorman, 1992). Tariffs would be adjusted on a product-by-product basis (rather
than being applied uniformly to all exports from an offending country) to negate the
competitive advantage gained due to substandard products. According to this strategy,
tariffs would be based on a country's own standards.
In his brief paper, Rothstein (1993) outlines why he thinks the United States should
prioritize improving working conditions in developing countries. According to him, the
34
consequences of slow growth in the developing world are rarely considered in policy
debates. Hence, he proposes, the opportunity to submit complaints with the commission
should be granted to workers or enterprises that claim to have suffered a competitive
disadvantage because another NAFTA member has failed to observe agreed upon labor
standards. The commission should have the authority to impose compensation tariffs or
limit cross-border commerce in the relevant product if it finds that labor standards have
been violated. The NAFTA countries should set up a "social tariff" to protect North
American standards from being eroded by low-wage imports from countries outside of
NAFTA. To prevent low-wage imports from non-NAFTA countries from undermining
North American standards, the NAFTA countries should implement a "social
tariff" (Rothstein, 1993). In summary, the idea for a social tariff would have workers and/or
businesses that feel they have been disadvantaged by unfair competition from foreign
enterprises who exploit lower standards petition an established authority for restitution in
the form of a tariff. The authority would make a decision based on the merits of the petition
after hearing evidence from both sides. The goal of the social tariff strategy is to eliminate
competitive advantages gained at the expense of the environment or workers' rights.
By safeguarding domestic employees and the environment, as well as pushing
foreign producers to improve their labor and environmental standards, proponents of social
tariffs claim this method can help to achieve fair trade. However, critics point out that
social tariffs are difficult to administer and enforce and might result in trade disputes and
retaliation. To promote equitable trade, governments have implemented social tariff
regimes, which are essentially import levies. Tariffs are used with the intention of leveling
the playing field between domestic producers and their foreign competitors, especially in
35
sectors where labor and environmental standards are lax in the exporting country. Social
tariffs are based on the idea that home companies and workers should be protected from
cheap imports by imposing higher taxes on items produced in countries with worse labor
and environmental standards. This strategy would also push international manufacturers to
raise their working conditions and environmental protections to compete in the U.S.
market. A government may raise tariffs on clothing made in countries with lower labor
standards in order to safeguard its domestic clothing industry and its workers. This would
provide international apparel manufacturers an incentive to raise their working conditions
so they can compete in the U.S. market.
2.5.2.1. Social Index Tariff Structure (SITS)
DeMartino, Moyer, Watkins’s (2014) thought experiment on fair trade is a worth
mentioning proposal under social tariff regimes. This experiment is an attempt to propose
a method of ethical trade. It advocates for capability-based development, equality, and
worldwide economic integration. SITS regime could be a global trade system that promotes
positive trade performance and growth while penalizing export-promoting policies that
harm human development, equality, or sustainability social tariffs at the multilateral level
(DeMartino et al., 2014).
In this approach, an index number is assigned to each country based on its efficacy
in promoting the average capabilities of its population relative to its means, sharing these
capabilities evenly, and displaying a commitment to sustainability. This index ranks the
capabilities of nations, and would encourage similar countries to trade with each other.
Under this approach, a social tariff will be imposed when one country exports to another
36
with a higher index number. SITS regime construction entails a number of judgment-based
processes. SITS, on the other hand, reveals the normative ideals that underpin any
international trading regime, which is a positive thing.
It begins with a capability performance measure for the country. The yearly UNDP
Human Development Index (HDI) produced by the HDR is a first approximation of a
capability indicator that allows for worldwide comparisons (DeMartino et al., 2014). The
HDI takes into account income, life expectancy, and education, and the countries are
ranked based on their human development.
5
Since, systemic injustice is frequently caused
by class, gender, ethnicity, color, and other variables, and they fall short of
capabilities equality, therefore, further data is required to create a capability-equality index
In the lack of good cross-national data, income inequality data was used as a proxy for
these various types of inequality. In the absence of a consensus measure of wealth or
income inequality, SITS computations use the GINI coefficient for income, which is
relevant and available for most countries (DeMartino et al., 2014).
The global SITS index highlights countries that have made significant social
improvement. Unlike the free trade regime, which affects FDI inflows and trade
performance, the SITS regime would reward governments that improve labor and
environmental standards with development assistance and increased access to global
markets. SITS protects employees and communities from global neoliberalism's
temptations to accept lower wages and less protective standards in order to stay employed.
5
The HDI is a composite indicator that does not directly reflect capability disparities across countries.
37
In contrast to global neoliberalism, the SITS system promotes human growth, equality, and
sustainability while punishing those who do not. The SITS regime's index component
determination and weighting, tariff band groupings, tariff sizes, conditions under which
nations in distress due to natural or societal disruptions might opt out of SITS or be granted
unrestricted access to others' markets, and so on are all customizable. Political, economic,
normative, and practical issues all influence trading systems. SITS is purposefully unclear.
This component of SITS assists in balancing the various concerns and aims that are usually
present in global policy frameworks.
The authors of this thought experiment deem it as ethical since it requires wealthy
countries to contribute the most and provides low-income countries with human
development resources. To help low-income countries from trade, SITS revenues may only
be distributed to countries with GDP per capita less than a multiple of the global average.
Tariffs for SITS reflect capabilities, whereas development funding may be motivated by
present operations. As a result, good performance leads to lower SITS fines but not awards,
increasing a country's net benefit. SITS enhances performance by increasing market
competitiveness and revenue distribution. It protects high-performing employees (for
example, those with robust labor laws) and motivates low-performing employees. A SITS
regime promotes a free trade order by requiring countries to pursue comparative advantage
in ways that advance the regime's objectives.
The SITS experiment advocates for human and worker rights as the foundation of
capabilities, and therefore, delineates that trade regimes must priorities subjects as worker
and human rights, labor passivity, low salaries, gender-based oppression encompassing
38
physical coercion over women's bodies, unequal household chores, discrimination in
formal labor markets and public institutions under the state law. Human abilities are
influenced by environmental quality. Environmentalism gives future generations power.
For justice, fair trade must support ecological sustainability. Environmental performance
should be measured. Environmental indices rank countries. For each indicator, long-term
public health or ecological sustainability goals are established through international
standards, leading national regulatory requirements, or scientific agreement (Emerson et
al., 2012). It is concerned with growth strategies and their outcomes. SITS would penalize
labor exploitation and environmental degradation in global markets. SITS that promotes
trade. SITS has no impact on globalization. The dynamics of trade and investment promote
human growth, equality, and sustainability. Incentives for market integration shift. "X"
methods must be excluded from competition because they promise victory at the expense
of political, economic, and environmental devastation (DeMartino, 2000).
2.5.3. The Sullivan Principles Approach
Another approach would be for wealthy nations to mandate that their home
companies operating abroad respect basic human and environmental rights while investing
in poorer nations. Drawing parallels to the "Sullivan Principles," which mandated that
American companies with assets in South Africa at the time of apartheid abide by
American anti-discrimination laws, Jagdish Bhagwati (1993), a proponent of free
trade, proposed this technique in the context of North American integration. Bhagwati, a
staunch free trade advocate, only recommended this course of action as a last resort to calm
39
the anti-NAFTA emotions that threatened to sink the accord. This plan can be understood
as exemplifying fair trade ideals regardless of its origins or the intentions of its architect.
Critics have labeled the relocation of businesses from high-standard countries to
poor countries as "social dumping," and the Sullivan Principles aim to put an end to this
trend. Followers of Bhagwati believe this tactic effectively eradicates social dumping
without encroaching on the sovereignty of the host country. We've seen that Bhagwati
disagrees with holding less-developed nations to the same criteria as more-advanced
nations. It would be an affront to their independence, he says, and their economy would
suffer as a result.
While critics of NAFTA have called for other signatories to adopt strong
environmental regulations similar to those in the United States, this idea has been roundly
rejected by Bhagwati. He elaborated that in the similar manner that United States prioritize
different areas and sectors when allocating funds to meet its environmental goals, so must
other signatories. It is ridiculous to assume that other trading partners will adopt a specific
country’s norms and values, which are nonsensical because that country would not accept
them if they were crafted by anybody other than themselves. He further argues that no
nation should be forced to adopt the development policies of another. While the concept of
sovereignty is important, it must be weighed against the competing idea of equal freedoms
to pursue goals that individuals have reason to value. The Sullivan principle was a close
second to the free trade system in Bhagwati's estimation. He felt that the method preserved
the sovereignty of poor countries while yet addressing the main concerns of fair traders
(DeMartino, 2000).
40
Therefore, the goal is to craft policies that encourage this result without requiring
all nations to take the same action. In this respect, the Sullivan Principles falls short. The
lack of mechanisms to guarantee that the higher standards are implemented throughout the
low-standard countries receiving investment is a major flaw in the proposal. It discourages
FDI while offering no proactive inducement (like money) to boost QC at home. Only a
small fraction of the people engaged by multinational corporations from underdeveloped
countries are affected. As Bhagwati sees it, this might have a "demonstration impact,"
encouraging NGOs and other groups to push for widespread adoption of the higher
standards enforced by international firms. This thesis does mention the shortcomings of
this proposal, however, providing an alternative better solutions is beyond the scope of this
research.
Given the relatively weak rights to association and political speech in many low-
income countries, it is debatable whether this demonstrable influence will be sufficient to
achieve universal improvements in rights and living standards without extra steps. Like the
social tariff system, the Sullivan Principles policy leads nowhere. It is seen that
unilateralism can be used for nationalist aims that have little to do with the policy's original
motivation, despite any economists’ praise. The African National Congress fought against
this method when it was employed to exert pressure on South Africa (ANC). The African
National Congress (ANC) was accused of caring more about the profits of foreign firms
than about the welfare of black South Africans (DeMartino, 2000).
2.6 Conclusion
This chapter analyzed the developments in fair trade theory’s advocacy in context
with its historical background, the perspective which is relevant to our study, and its
41
policies and practices under organized purview. It was found that nearly every single
contemporary industrialized country has, at some point in the course of their economic
development, enacted severe rules and regulations, as well as formulated its own
requirements prior to participating in trade liberalization. Therefore, the big trading entities
like WTO essentially include the freedom for contemporary developing countries to
practice their policy autonomy and formulate their own fair trade polices when they enter
in trade agreements. These entities should be there mediate the agreements and not impose
the liberalization restrictions as favorable for the developed countries. Not only this, but
the main goal of any international trade agreement should also be to ensure that human
development and environmental conservations takes indefinite lead over merely generating
trade flows and profits. This will be discussed further in detail in Chapter 3.
Chang and Green (2003) present favorable argument as:
“The tightening-up of foreign investment regulation after the
Second World War by these three countries (UK, France and
Germany) reflected the changes in their status in the world
of international investment. As they exchanged places with
the USA, becoming net recipients of FDI, rather than net
providers, they adopted the same restrictions on foreign
investment that they had previously criticized when the USA
had used them. This suggests that countries have used, and
indeed should use, different policies towards foreign
investment according to their role as investment providers or
receivers. Since developing countries are today almost
always at the receiving end, it follows that they too need, and
should be allowed to have, significantly more freedom to
regulate foreign investment in their long-term interest than
do the developed countries.” (p. 16)
The chapter defends the point of view of various heterodox economists and social
and human rights activists in favor of adopting an internationalist egalitarian perspective
42
in criticism to mainstream view of free trade, since 1990s. It provides a background,
context and two important economic framework that can be analyzed to understand and
champion for a fair trade regime. Many heterodox economists pursued a rather
comprehensive movement to advocate for multilateral fair trade regime (DeMartino, 2014).
Economic policy makers, if they really want humanity as a whole, and individual societies
within, to develop to its full potential and become an ideal society needs to divorce from
their fetishism with increased economic returns and focus on devising policies that
prioritize human development and environmental conservation.
43
Chapter 3: A Brief History of International Trade Theories and their Impact on
Globalization
3.1 Introduction
There still exists wide global consensus on free trade as the best international trade
policy. Many economists still advocate their believes that free trade is the only way to go
if nations want to achieve economic development and growth. The United
States adopted a protectionist strategy in the early years after its independence from Britain
in 1776. Protection of home producers from foreign competition and encouragement of
economic self-sufficiency were among the goals behind the placement of tariffs on
imported products. There was a trend toward free trade advocacy in the United States in
the 19th century, a time of great industrialization and economic prosperity. It was only after
the World War II that United States “liberalized its trade and tarted championing the cause
of free trade” (Chang, 2007). The thesis analyzes this argument in depth later in this
chapter. David Ricardo's theory of comparative advantage, which argued that countries can
benefit from specializing in producing goods or services in which they have a comparative
advantage and engaging in trade with other countries for goods or services in which they
do not have a comparative advantage, is largely credited with popularizing the concept of
free trade (Chang, 2007).
In short, depending on the economic and political climate of the time, the United
States implemented a variety of protectionist and free trade policies throughout the late
44
19th and early 20th century. Economic and political factors, such as the need to
safeguard domestic industries, raise funds, and resolve labor issues, prompted the
imposition or removal of tariffs. Following WWII, the United States took the lead in
establishing the Bretton Woods system and other international economic institutions that
would foster global economic stability and free trade. The United States has engaged in
several trade talks and accords, and it played a pivotal role in the establishment of
international institutions like the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT), which
evolved into the World Trade Organization (WTO).
There have been several official free trade accords signed based on this
unwarranted support of the free trade as the ultimate international trade strategy. For
instance, the U.S.-Peru Trade Promotion Agreement was signed into law in 2007 by
President George W. Bush (PTPA). By lowering tariffs and other trade barriers, this
agreement sought to increase commerce between the United States and Peru.
6
Once the
North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) expired in 1994, the United States signed
the PTPA as its first FTA. Since the U.S.-Colombia Trade Promotion Agreement in 2006,
this was the first trade pact inked between a South American country and the United States.
This treaty entered into force on February 1, 2009, after being passed by the United States
Congress in November 2007. Many businesses backed it because they believed it would
boost exports and create jobs, but unions and environmentalists opposed it because they
feared it would promote outsourcing and do harm to workers and the environment.
6
It also included provisions to further safeguard workers' rights and the environment.
45
This chapter will critically analyze the old trade models and the new trade model
that have been the fundamental basis of free trade proposals proposed, accepted, and
implemented globally. It is important to note that mostly these FTAs are heavily supported
by the economies of global north with the help of international financial institutions.
3.2 Theoretical Limitations of International Trade Theories
This section provides a brief critical summary of old trade and new trade theories
to understand the dynamic of globalization. Some of the theories included are just to
understand the evolution of international trade practices and theories, and their in-depth
analysis is beyond the scope of this study.
3.2.1. Mercantilism
During the period spanning from the mid-sixteenth century to the late eighteenth
century, the trade policy formulation and implementation in a majority of European nations
were primarily influenced by the philosophy of mercantilism, as noted by Heckscher (1931)
and Magnusson (1994). According to the theory, the most effective approach to
augmenting wealth was through global trade and expansion of territories. There were
certain advantages observed, including an increase in commercial operations. According
to Viner's (1937) analysis, the mercantilist school of thought posited that the principal
objective of commerce was to attain a "favorable" balance of trade, which was
characterized by an excess of export revenues relative to import expenditures. The main
objective was to enhance the country's economic prosperity through specific means, such
as diminishing imports and elevating exports, promoting the growth of domestic
46
businesses, and procuring colonies to gain entry to their innate resources (Irwin, 1996;
O'Brien & Williams, 2016).
The British Navigation Act of 1651 exemplifies a mercantilist trade policy that was
prevalent during that era, as noted by Taylor (1972) and Wallerstein (1980). According to
Wallerstein's (1980) account, transportation of imports originating from continental Europe
was restricted to British ships or those registered in the country of origin. Additionally,
foreign vessels were prohibited from engaging in coastal trade activities within England.
Mercantilism has faced criticism on multiple fronts within academic discourse. Initially, a
multitude of economists who advocated for free trade held the belief that the prioritization
of amassing valuable metals was misguided. Instead, they argued that a country's economic
well-being should be assessed based on its output and utilization of goods and services.
The mercantilist trade policy exhibited a hostile stance towards multilateral trade
agreements, as it involved the imposition of import taxes and quotas, and the prohibition
of the shipment of industrial equipment, raw materials, and skilled personnel, with the aim
of supporting domestic industries. Adam Smith and David Hume (1752) were notable
critics of the mercantilist theory, as noted by Viner (1937). Smith emphasized the
importance of free trade and specialization, primarily due to their contribution to economic
growth. The analysis conducted by Smith investigates the impact of implementing a
fundamental mercantilist principle, which involves the imposition of tariffs or embargoes
on commodities produced abroad. According to the author's definition, the aforementioned
"restraints" confer advantages to particular domestic sectors, as indicated by the user. The
imposition of a tariff on imported goods results in an increase in their cost, while a complete
prohibition may lead to a corresponding escalation in the cost of smuggling them.
47
Consequently, there exists a comparative reduction in the expenses of domestically
produced commodities of analogous kind, potentially leading to a circumstance where local
manufacturers attain a predominant stance in the regional marketplace. Under conditions
of restricted trade, purchasers tend to demonstrate a higher level of readiness to pay an
elevated price premium, as opposed to scenarios where trade is not restricted.
According to Smith's analysis, the imposition of such restrictions has a negative
effect on the well-being of the populace, as individuals strive to optimize the utilization of
their available resources. The proposition put forth by the author suggests that the
intervention of the government in this specific process would impede its advancement.
When the potential benefits are comparable, individuals tend to favor domestic trade and
transportation of goods over international trade, owing to the relatively lower risks
associated with the former. As per the author's assertion, a significant increase in import
costs could dissuade their importation, leading to a reduction in customs revenue due to the
decrease in imported goods outweighing the augmented charges.
According to Smith's assertion, there exist specific circumstances where limitations
on imports are considered necessary. The author's proposal entails the cessation of
importing commodities from companies involved in activities related to warfare, in order
to promote their growth within the national market. It can be argued that if domestic items
are taxed, it is justifiable to subject foreign items to the same taxation. The author cautions
against expediting the reduction of import tariffs or relaxing import limitations as a means
of preventing potential disruption to the domestic economy. Smith presents a pessimistic
viewpoint regarding the likelihood of trade liberalization, which he attributes to the
48
influence of politicians and their affluent supporters who advocate for protectionist
policies.
Smith argues that the imposition of import restrictions has negative consequences
for both business enterprises and ethical values. The author's literary work is based on the
concept of "innate entitlements" (Smith, 1776), which serves as the primary source of his
indignation and the viewpoints expressed therein. According to Smith's analysis, the
prohibition on exporting sheep and grain is considered a violation of the right to utilize
one's own resources to the fullest extent possible. The infringement of this fundamental
right could be deemed necessary for a critical objective, such as readiness for military
confrontation. Mercantilism, according to
Wallerstein (1980) facilitated both imperialism and exploitation. According to
Smith (1776), the implementation of mercantilist policies such as protectionism and tariffs
resulted in heightened international tensions and reduced commerce, ultimately leading to
trade wars. According to Smith's assertion, the implementation of import tariffs tends to
benefit merchants primarily, without being a necessary outcome. Smith asserted that the
implementation of free trade would yield advantages for all parties concerned.
Additionally, he refuted the concept that a nation's affluence was predominantly reliant on
its accumulation of gold and silver. Several economists have posited that mercantilist
practices were employed to justify the appropriation of resources and labor from colonies
and other countries. The outcome of this phenomenon was the
proliferation of destitution and a surge in disparities.
49
3.2.2. Classical Economic Theory:
Adam Smith, in his revolutionary manuscript "The Wealth of Nations," published
in 1776, presented classical trade theory and specifically the principle of absolute
advantage that laid the foundations of free trade across. Smith rationalized that nations
should focus their production efforts on the kind of commodities at which they have a
absolute competitive advantage, and should engage in trade with other nations in order to
acquire the types of things that they are unable to produce as effectively (Appleyard &
Field et al. 2006). According to the notion of absolute advantage
7
, nations should focus on
exporting those products which they can produce efficiently and inexpensively as
compared to all other nations. Then, in return, they should buy from nations that do have
an absolute edge in the products they import, driving up global prosperity via more trade.
Absolute advantage is the foundation for enormous profits that result from trading between
diverse producers of commodities that each have their own distinct absolute advantages
(Smith, 1776).
Smith, in 1776, made his feted case for free trade. "Free trade", over time, attained
an intellectual status that remained unchallenged by any other doctrine at that time (Irwin
1996, Viner 1937). Gradually, the proposition that freedom to trade internationally is more
favorable than protectionism for an economy, both individually and as a whole, endured a
lot of criticism but remained relevant and widely supported. Smith puts forward the
7
Adam Smith pioneered the school of thought known as "laissez-faire" economics, which holds that a free
market driven by competitive, self-interested actors would naturally achieve a state of efficiency that
promotes increased output and wealth creation. Smith (1776) writes in Wealth of Nations that the greatest
advance in the productive capacities of work is the result of the division of labor. His famous pin factory
example is the clearest illustration of this. The concept of absolute advantage is a worldwide extension of his
concept of division of labor.
50
proposition that, for the general opulence—state of high consumption amongst all the
societies, each and every single society is to be exposed to a global market where
production and specialization take place in various labor forms (Meek and Skinner 1973).
According to Appleyard and Field et al., (2006), one of the most essential reasons that
Adam Smith favored free trade was the availability of necessary market for increased
output resulting from the division of production at industrial level. Aspromourgos (2009)
further explains that if the global market is exposed to the variety of specialized labor (free
international trade), it will facilitate the extension of the benefits of division of labor to
other societies (economies) around the globe. This will favor general opulence globally.
There are plenty of assumptions that Smith makes for his idea of absolute advantage
to work efficiently. First, he assumes that labor is the only factor of production, and the
relative number of labor unites required for production translates the cost of production.
However natural resources and capital also determine the costs of production, which in turn
determines the prices. This theory is also a very simplified version involving only two
countries and two commodities; hence this assumption divorces the theory from the
realities and complexities of the real world, and simply assumes that the international trade
is merely all about bilateral agreements. Smith also assumes no costs of trading goods
across borders, which is completely detached from the reality of variation in prices and
production depending on transportation costs. For the global division of labor, providing
low-tech inputs may not be as valuable as being further up the value chain. In the absence
of an industrial policy to supersede free trade theory, the historical record shows that free
markets in the Third World simply meant deadly competition from experienced foreign
firms before local enterprises had sufficient playing field to compete with international
51
prices. This was true even in the most labor-intensive manufacturing industries, where low
wages were no match for the knowledge of advanced countries.
In short, this classical theory of economics is founded on a number of assumptions,
the most important of which are that trade is advantageous to all parties involved, that there
are no costs or impediments to trade caused by transportation, and that means of production
are not transportable across nations. Moreover, it presupposes that markets are fully
competitive and that prices adjust in such a way as to guarantee that every nation specializes
in the production of the items in which it has a comparative advantage (Amsden, 2008).
Therefore, the classical trade theory has been criticized on the grounds that it does not
adequately take into account the impact that technological advancements, economies of
scale, and other variables that might influence patterns of trade can have. They further say
that it does not address problems like as income inequality and the distributional impacts
of trade, both of which are major concerns in today's society. The framework illustrates
that absolute cost trade will benefit technologically sophisticated economies and force poor
nations to produce inexpensive labor and raw commodities (Shaikh 2003). He explains that
this paradigm convincingly demonstrates that trade based on absolute costs would benefit
technologically sophisticated industrialized economies while pushing poor nations down
the ladder in exchange for cheap labor and raw resources.
If absolute advantage is to be accepted as an accurate notion, and the nations use
division of labor to reap benefits from international trade, all the countries require
infrastructure to execute Smith’s idea to enjoy the wealth created by production process
separation while continually improving their production methods, equipment, etc. It is
highly unlikely that all the world's poorest countries would benefit from this type of
52
universal luxury, especially if research and development are mandatory prerequisites.
Theoretically, the poor nations should take part in universal opulence, however, their
capabilities and access to the market are restricted to only participate by producing primary
goods and raw materials. Therefore, developing nations can contribute to division of
production operations and enjoy its universal opulence if they have a strong domestic
market, manufactures to trade, technological advances, etc., but not so much if they are in
the low-technology parts of the chain and certainly not if they are only supplying primary
goods, according to their absolute advantage. In heterodox economics, the notion of
absolute advantage has been revived to better comprehend trade within the context of
competitive advantage.
Despite these critiques, the classical theory of trade, especially the notion of
absolute advantage, continues to be a significant topic in economics. It has also affected
debates on trade policy and international trade agreements. This thesis affirms, regardless
of its shortcomings, the idea of absolute advantage continues to serve as a cornerstone of
classical trade theory, building upon the work of earlier economists.
8
Smith's concept of absolute advantage served as the foundation for David Ricardo's
theory of comparative advantage. Ricardo refined Smith’s idea that a nation “A” is also
able to manufacture a product at an opportunity cost
9
lower than that of another nation “B”,
8
Globally, the way nations think about and act upon international trade and specialization in production is
largely attributable to the notion of absolute advantage and classical trade theory more generally. While being
critiqued and improved upon throughout time, the theory's fundamental concepts are still useful in modern
economic discussion. The classical trade theory served as the basis for the development of a new school of
thought known as neoclassical trade theory, which was developed in the latter half of the 19th century and
the early 20th century. It places a strong emphasis on the part that market forces and individual decision-
making play in defining trade patterns and the consequences they have on welfare.
9
The value of the next best option that is not taken advantage of to generate a thing is referred to as the
opportunity cost of that thing.
53
then nation “A” has a comparative advantage over nation “B”. The idea was, that even if a
nation does not seize an absolute advantage in production of any good or service in the
global economy, according to Ricardo's theory, it should focus on producing items for
which it possesses a comparative advantage (Ricardo, 1817; Samuelson, 1948). This
enables nations to increase their total production of commodities and reap the benefits of
increased commerce. Ricardo, whilst extending Smith’s idea, also favors international trade
with the most important underlying assumption that there are no transaction costs (i.e.,
trade is completely free). He presented the concept of comparative advantage and proposed
that the countries should focus on the production of the good with the lowest production
opportunity cost (1817). The idea of comparative advantage is the central tenet of the
neoclassical school of thought in economics and commerce. Opportunity cost is included
into the equation, and the potential advantages from trade due to nations specializing in the
production of items for which they have the lowest opportunity cost are highlighted.
One of the major arguments against the idea of comparative advantage is that it is
based on unrealistic assumptions, such as perfect competition and full employment
(Stiglitz, 2019). The underlying assumptions of the comparative advantage model makes it
difficult to apply it to the real-world scenarios and thus make the argument for free trade
invalid. Prasch (1996) argues that these assumptions fail in practice. The model does not
account for the externalities and assume that the total private costs are equal to the total
social costs. This model further assumes constant returns to scale and perfect competition
to imply that trade can only arise based on the comparative advantage. Another problematic
assumption is the perfect mobility of the factors of production from one industry to another.
The labor in industrial goods production cannot effortlessly shift and contribute to the
54
production of agricultural goods—there are transitions costs that might be quite large, that
are ignored by the comparative static nature of the models. In case of developing countries,
many industries, such as electronics and clothing, will be wiped out by the imports based
on comparative advantage. This will result in outflow of labor from threatened industries
to absorb into the informal sector. This labor transfer will reduce the standard of living and
the overall well-being of developing nations.
Since, developing and developed economies have quite dissimilar production
structures. Therefore, for free trade to be mutually beneficial based on comparative
advantage, production possibility frontiers and comparable costs need to exist in the first
place. The most concerning drawback of Ricardo’s comparative advantage theory is
embedded in its sole focus on static, short-term gain in a single period. Which is also holds
for the Heckscher-Ohlin model. It completely overlooks the need to expand production
capacity for sustainable economic development and prosperity over the long-term. Palley
(2006) concludes:
“Although there are always gains from trade, countries can
suffer from further globalization – their future gains from trade
may fall, making them worse off than before. This sobering
conclusion derives from pure trade theory, which assumes away
macroeconomic problems such as unemployment, trade deficits,
and financial instability. When these problems are factored in,
the case for strategic trade policy becomes even stronger.” (p. 5)
The notion of comparative advantage is nevertheless an important part of
international economics and commerce, regardless of these criticisms. The scope of the
theory has been broadened by some researchers to include issues including technological
transfer, institutional quality, and political economy (Helpman & Krugman, 1985; Rodrik,
55
1995; Acemoglu et al., 2012). Throughout the course of the last two centuries, the idea of
comparative advantage has been the subject of intense scrutiny and development. While it
has been criticized for its assumptions and limitations by some academics, it is nevertheless
used by others as a lens through which to examine the pros and cons of a liberal
international commerce. Over the course of the previous two centuries, researchers have
improved and expanded upon this idea, and a wealth of literature has been produced
investigating its applications and caveats.
3.2.3. Neo-classical Economic Theory
Developing on the traditional theory of comparative advantage, the Heckscher-
Ohlin theory (also known as the factor-proportions theory) was formulated in the early 20th
century. In the 1920s and 1930s, two Swedish economists, Eli Heckscher and Bertil Ohlin,
independently developed a hypothesis based on the premise that the level of technology in
trade nations is similar and that each country has a specific level of factor endowment in
either of the two factors of production in a very simplified model (Heckscher, 1919; Ohlin,
1933). According to this economic theory, nations would focus on exporting and importing
products that make the most of their plentiful resources for making certain types of
commodities (Samuelson, 1948). Neoclassical trade theory presents the notion of the
Heckscher-Ohlin model, which explains trade patterns on the basis of disparities in the
factor endowments of different countries. The model predicts that nations would export
products that make use of their plentiful factors of production while simultaneously
importing products that make use of their limited factors of production (Heckscher, 1919).
56
The Heckscher-Ohlin Model (1933) proposed that the economies should produce
the commodities that extensively require their abundant factor endowment (either labor or
capital), and the free international trade of a specific commodity derived from the abundant
factor endowment will result in price convergence across the two trading parties. Among
the foundational assumptions upon which Heckscher-Ohlin theory is built are free-market
competition, consistent returns to scale, and factor immobility across nations (Stolper &
Samuelson, 1941). With this paradigm, we can see why some nations export products that
make extensive use of their plentiful factors while others import products that make
extensive use of their scarce elements (Leamer, 1980). When nations' factor endowments
change over time, the theory predicts that trade will cause a convergence in factor prices
(Vanek, 1968).
The subsequent presumptions serve as the foundation for the Heckscher-Ohlin
theory's theoretical framework: different countries have varied resources, or endowments
of factors, of the elements of production, such as labor and capital, economies throughout
the world employ the same production technology to manufacture the same items; the
market is said to have perfect competition when there is no way for any one entity to
influence either the price or the quantity of goods or services being offered, the production
process displays constant returns to scale, which means that output grows proportionately
with inputs as the size of the operation increases (Subasat, 2002). In essence, this idea
proposed that a nation will export commodities that make use of the plentiful factors of
production in its economy and buy items that make use of the scarce factors of production
in its economy. For instance, a nation that has a plentiful supply of labor would export
products that are labor-intensive and import those that are capital-intensive.
57
Prasch (1996) argues that it is problematic to assume that two countries have static
set of technologies (know-how). That’s a critique for both the comparative advantage
theory by Ricardo and Heckscher-Ohlin model. For instance, in case of global south, the
model assumes that it is abundant in unskilled labor and compares it with global north
which is well endowed with skilled labor. However, skilled labor is not a resource that
should be taken as given, instead it is developed over time. According to the H-O Model,
developing countries’ given level of unskilled labor is its natural endowment, and therefore,
it again fails to take into consideration the economic development over time. The reason
behind this is that it is not a dynamic model, and like comparative advantage, it promises
just a one-time jump in consumption.
If developing nations were to identify the unskilled labor as their potential natural
endowment and produce the unskilled labor abundant goods, it will mean ignoring their
potential to create new sets of endowments (like capital and skilled labor) to ensure the
economic prosperity and development over time. Further, H-O Model assumes perfect
competition and constant returns to scale, and emphasis only on factor endowments to
initiate trade flows (Krugman, 1987).
Subasat (2009) points out that according to this model, the trade possibilities are
greater amongst the countries that are dissimilar in their endowments. Theoretically, it
implies that developing nations and developed nations should have greater trade
possibilities, however, historical, and present evidence shows us that the most frequent and
beneficial trade is happening between the countries within Global North (and since then,
with China, which he doesn’t account for). He believes that the trade flows driven by the
abundant factor intensive outputs is rather obvious, and therefore it fails to provide any
58
convincing evidence about how a country could benefit from specializing in production of
their abundant factor intensive goods.
Subasat (2009) argues that factors of production are not only naturally existing, but
they can also be produced; for instance, labor can be trained, and capital can be created. In
case of free trade agreement between global north and global south, the advocates of factor
endowment theory might argue that trade openness will gradually shift the production of
unskilled labor-intensive commodities to skilled labor-intensive commodities. However,
this should then suggest an opposite shift (from skilled labor-intensive commodities to
unskilled labor-intensive commodities) in global north. This model merely gives us the
idea of how a country would behave under the free trade regime and not how they should
behave to promote economic development and prosperity-the main argument in favor of
fair trade. These are not models of economic development at all.
The Heckscher-Ohlin theory has been criticized for a number of reasons, the most
prominent of which are its assumptions of perfect competition and the homogeneity of
labor and capital inputs (Lall & Streeten, 1977; Deardorff, 1984). Moreover, the model
disregards the impact of technological development and creative thinking on comparative
advantage (Kravis, 1956). Yet, the Heckscher-Ohlin theory is still widely used as a model
for analyzing intranational and international commerce and income distribution (Markusen,
1986; Feenstra & Taylor, 2014). The neoclassical trade theory, in its whole, offers a
theoretical framework for studying the impacts of international trade on welfare and the
allocation of resources, and it has had a key influence on trade policy throughout the 20th
century. Nevertheless, critiques of the assumptions and predictions of neoclassical trade
theory have led to the creation of alternative trade theories, such as the new trade theory
59
and the political economy approach. These theories have been developed in response to
these concerns.
Further, the Heckscher-Ohlin theory has been expanded and modified in a variety
of different ways, including as the Stolper-Samuelson theorem (1941), which predicts that
free trade would lead to a redistribution of wealth amongst factors of production inside a
nation. In general, this thesis does not deny that the HeckscherOhlin theory continues to be
an essential addition to the area of international trade theory and has had a substantial
impact on the administration of trade policy.
3.2.4. New Trade Theory
In the 1980s, a new school of trade theory arose that aimed to improve upon the
neoclassical model of international commerce by include such concepts as economies of
scale and imperfect competition. Being one of the first economists to argue that a
company's capacity to spread its fixed costs across a bigger output would provide it a
competitive advantage in international commerce, Krugman (1979) was among the first to
bring the notion of economies of scale into trade theory. Helpman and Krugman later
expanded on Krugman's work by creating a model that accounted for economies of scale
and imperfect competition (1985).
The conceptual framework of new trade theory is based on the following principles:
It is possible for companies to achieve economies of scale in their manufacturing processes,
resulting in a reduction in average costs as production volume increases. Imperfect
competition arises when companies possess some degree of market power, allowing them
60
to charge prices that exceed their actual costs. Companies also engage in product
differentiation, where they offer goods that are not perfect substitutes for one another.
According to the new trade theory, the dominance of certain nations in exporting
specific manufactured goods can be attributed to economies of scale. A country with a
substantial domestic market may have a comparative advantage in producing goods at a
lower cost per unit relative to a smaller country. As a result, the larger nation possesses a
competitive advantage in global trade. The novel trade theory elucidates the rationale
behind the engagement of nations in intra-industry trade, wherein nations are involved in
both importing and exporting of goods that are analogous to each other. This phenomenon
can be attributed to the ability of nations to specialize in the production of various iterations
of a particular product, leading to the emergence of product differentiation.
The model exhibited that firms manufacturing similar products within a particular
geographical area may form a cluster, thereby conferring them with a competitive
advantage in the international market. Baldwin (1989) expanded upon the concept of
clusters and proposed that governments could promote their growth through measures such
as investments in education and infrastructure. According to the speaker, trade agreements
may promote the development of clusters by facilitating the increased mobility of
commodities, money, and people.
This section elucidates the manner in which new trade theory effectively supplanted
the three primary argumentative foundations of the models in the old trade theories, namely
perfect competition, constant returns to scale, and homogenous goods. The novel trade
theory pertains to trade that is predicated on external economies or the amplification of
returns to scale. The concept of economies of scale provides nations with an incentive to
61
engage in specialization and exchange of goods and services. In cases where there are
increasing returns to scale, the industry's production will experience a more than
proportional increase when the inputs are doubled. In light of this, it can be observed that
economies in the global south are poised to benefit from lower production costs of raw
materials and primary goods in comparison to their global north counterparts, owing to the
relatively lower wages prevalent in these regions. Asymmetry is expected to exist, as noted
by Finlay (1984). One potential explanation for the initial advantage could be attributed to
the variances in unskilled labor supply between the northern and southern regions. Hence,
taking into account all pertinent variables, it can be inferred that emerging economies are
poised to experience amplified returns to scale within their raw material and primary goods
sectors. The new trade theory proposes that developing nations should intervene by
providing subsidies to their industries that will experience increasing returns to scale.
The tenets of the new trade theory acknowledge the overall advantages of
liberalized trade, while also acknowledging the existence of circumstances in which such
benefits may not be realized. Given this circumstance, the emphasis transitions towards the
identification of specific circumstances in which trade can generate tangible benefits and
serve as a catalyst for economic development (Shaikh, 2003). Particularly in discussions of
regional trade agreements and the role of state in supporting economic growth, the new
trade theory has been formative (Krugman, 1981). It has been criticized, nevertheless, for
having such little empirical evidence and for failing to take into consideration variables
like the rate at which technology is evolving and regional variations in factor endowments
(Grossman & Helpman, 1995; Deardorff, 2005).
62
The idea of strategic trade policy is one of the most important things that modern
trade theory has contributed to the field of trade economics. This notion proposes that
governments may improve their country's competitiveness in specific sectors by offering
subsidies or other types of assistance (Krugman, 1981). This, on the other hand, has been
met with opposition and remains a contentious issue among economists. The evidence
analyzed in Chapter 3 will show that regardless of the case for intervention, the government
intervention has failed to tackle the issues of social and ecological imbalances. This thesis
shows that the intervention is mainly encouraged for protection of domestic industries and
not to hinder the labor and environmental exploitation.
3.3. A Critical Reassessment of Trade Models
Trade models served as the theoretical basis for the concept of free trade, which
advocates for the elimination of trade barriers and the promotion of international trade
based on each country's comparative advantage and increasing returns. However, the
assumptions of these models have been challenged for their lack of real world implication
and reductionism. This section examines the historical and intuitive evidence challenging
the free trade policies.
3.3.1. Historical Evidence Against Old Trade Theories
Chang (2002), as opposed to many economists, argues against the free trade policy
as a universal mandate for the developing countries. United States adopted industrialization
policies against the advice of Britain. Chang explains that Smith (1776) advised Americans
63
to adopt free trade policy and import the industrial goods from Britain than to manufacture
(and protect) them at home. Since, United States had comparative advantage in producing
agricultural goods (and exchanging for industrial goods). Even though the United States
was advised against the production of industrial goods and to stick with importing them,
they went ahead and introduced protectionist policies for their infant industries. For almost
a hundred years till the second world war, United States had the most protected economy
globally with the highest tariff rate in the world (Chang 2002). Soon after the end of second
world war, when United States achieved dominance, it started championing the free trade.
Countries that have more open trade regimes tend to experience faster economic growth.
Partially, this can be attributed to the benefits that are obtained as a result of transparency.
Openness can be considered a "forcing variable" as it influences policy decisions. Countries
with inward-oriented policies may be tempted to implement counterproductive policies,
but they may not be able to adopt them or may abandon them quickly if they have an
outward-oriented trade regime (Krueger, 1990).
Chang explains how the developed countries, while still in their developing stages,
did not practice what they are preaching to the current developing economies. United States
beacon of free trade, used more aggressive tariff protections than the countries (e.g.,
Germany and Japan) associated with state interventionism. He makes the argument that
tariff protection policies, export subsidies, research and development support, cartel
arrangements, infrastructure investments in many countries, specially United States and
Britain, were the crucial component of their sustainable economic development strategies.
Williams (1994) points out that Britain’s early capitalist development was centrally driven
64
by slavery and monopoly. Therefore, association of Britain’s industrial success to free trade
is a mere myth.
In the United States and Britain, agricultural development, propelled by
protectionist policies and other state interventions, expedited the process of industrial
development (Shafaeddin, 1998). In the United States, particularly, the state facilitated
capital accumulation, institutional development, infrastructural build-up, and Research &
Development training for development of the domestic economy. Chang (2002) sheds light
on how numerous successful economies, rather than using free trade, used strategic trade
policies and specific industrial policies to achieve dominance. He further gives the example
of China’s, India’s, and Mauritius’s economic growth to establish the fact that many
developing economies prospered under protectionist policies as opposed to what the free
trade advocates advise. Undoubtably, Chang advises developing countries against any strict
free-trade agreement proposed by the countries in global north. Chang demonstrated,
through his assiduous research, that the United States and Britain’s advice to emerging
economies regarding laissez-faire national industrial and free trade policies are completely
contradictory to the practices they themselves pursued to achieve dominance.
3.3.2. Deepening of globalization: Redefining Role of Government
During the 1990’s, campaign for the establishment of ‘fair trade’ regime by various
activists and heterodox economists, was discredited heavily by many leading trade theorists
including Krugman (DeMartino, 2014). Krugman, around 1960s, expansively argued that
taking fair trade position will harm third world countries the most. Alongside many other
65
free trade economists, he argued that fair trade is not a serious position, and it hurts the
very masses that it essentially claims to protect. He believes that the moral outrage amongst
the challengers of trade liberalization stems from their unreal expectations towards
production standards in Global South.
Some of the arguments made by neo-classical trade theorists against fair trade are
almost compelling. One of the arguments by Krugman (1997) for justification of free trade
is the lack of alternatives for the poor nations. He presented a thorough argument regarding
the competitive advantage that the Global South possesses in the global market due to their
low labor wages. Krugman asserts that the workers' limited access to alternative
employment options is the primary factor contributing to their meager compensation.
Producers prioritize cost minimization over improving healthcare and living standards for
workers. Therefore, laborers in developing nations are confronted with perilous work
environments regardless.
Another argument by Krugman was that the global poverty is not something caused
by the multinational corporation for profits but has persisted since long before. About two
decades ago, Bangladesh and Indonesia were only exporting raw materials while importing
most other manufactured goods whereas there was a rapid growth of some other small
Asian economies. The mere purpose of their own inefficient manufacturing sectors was to
serve domestic markets under import quota. The only improvements that have taken place
in these economies are the direct or indirect result of the actions of ‘soulless multinationals
and rapacious local entrepreneurs’, who take advantage of the cheap labor. According to
him, the lower wages have given these economies the competitive advantage in the global
markets.
66
Further, Krugman (1997) argues that given most of the starving rural populations
in the third world countries working as subsistent farmers, the wage laborers working at
slave wages in the garment and shoe factories are far better off. He gives the example of
how industrialization in poor economies like Indonesia, where people have preferred to
work as scavengers on garbage dump than any alternative jobs, had significantly improved
the lives of local people. The standards in Indonesia had been so poor, that the progress
was measured by the per capita consumption of calories. He explains that the relatively
higher wages in these industries was an incentive for people to move from alternative
sectors. Further, this growth of industry and creation of jobs had a ripple effect throughout
the country. As the burden on land decreased, the rural wages increased. The unemployed
labor force dwelling in cities in search of work started to shrink and the firms started
competing by offering higher wages. To support this argument, Krugman gives the
example of South Korea and Taiwan where he believes that this process went on for too
long and finally resulted in average wage approaching the wage of an American teen-ager
working at a McDonald’s.
He believes that the fair trade movements cause significantly more harm than the
good they suppose they will do. In 1993, there was a ban on imports from Bangladesh’s
textile firms if they had employed children. Therefore, the factories stopped employing
children. As a result, significant number of children were left out on streets, and a big chunk
of those were coerced into prostitution (Krugman, 1997). The call for harmonizing
production and labor standards for trade, therefore, is merely a lack of understanding of the
cultural and social paradigms in poor countries. Employment in the industries serving the
needs of multinational corporations is way better than alternatives. The only way possible
67
for these developing nations to be able to export manufactured goods is their competitive
advantage due to having cheap labor and poor labor standards. In Krugman’s (1997) own
words:
“The point is that third-world countries aren't poor because
their export workers earn low wages; it's the other way
around. Because the countries are poor, even what look to us
like bad jobs at bad wages are almost always much better
than the alternatives: millions of Mexicans are migrating to
the north of the country to take the low-wage export jobs that
outrage opponents of NAFTA. And those jobs wouldn't exist
if the wages were much higher: the same factors that make
poor countries poor -- low productivity, bad infrastructure,
general social disorganization -- mean that such countries
can compete on world markets only if they pay wages much
lower than those paid in the West.” (para. 6)
In addition to Krugman, many other neo-classicals had opposed fair trade
harmonization of environmental and labor standards. Bhagwati and Srinivasan (1996),
argue that the differential environmental standards of developing countries are simply due
to the differences in endowments and technologies across the countries. The neoclassical
economists claim that the development of David Ricardo’s theory of comparative
advantage considers the climate and technology in reference to culture relativism and
subjective priorities, and therefore, advocates that free trade will maximize global welfare.
Bhagwati contests that countries, based on their natural differences in priorities, will assign
importance to various environmental externalities. For instance, a country depending upon
its technology and endowments may want to prioritize people not dying of starvation than
saving the dolphins and reducing ecological degradation.
In short, the Krugman almost three decades ago, in his multiple books and articles,
recognized almost every opponent of free trade and globalization as fool who is unable to
68
understand the field of economics very well. He bluntly called the fearful commentary on
economic competition with nations with lower labor and environmental standards, like
China, as ridiculous. He did not want the US labor force to worry too much about the
globalization, as it will only have an insignificant impact on their prosperity. Fair traders
who think that their cries are to help the poor exploited workers in third world countries
are only halting the developing nations’ overall progress and maybe even reversing the
some they had achieved through globalization.
Interestingly, in 2007, Paul Krugman tepidly switched his stance on fair trade
movements. He does not do so by advocating for fair industrialization in the developing
countries, but rather the protection of less-educated, unskilled American workers.
According to his opinion, as the import of labor-intensive goods from third world countries
is increasing, the wage of American un-skilled labor is rapidly decreasing. While in 1996
Krugman believed that the US workers should not worry about the impact of globalization
on their prosperity, the recently suspicious 2007 Krugman reasons that persistent free trade
agreements with third world countries will damage the American workers the most.
“By all means, let’s have strong labor standards in our
pending trade agreements, and let’s approach proposals for
new agreements with an appropriate degree of skepticism.
But if Democrats really want to help American workers,
they’ll have to do it with a pro-labor policy that relies on
better tools than trade policy. Universal health care, paid for
by taxing the economy’s winners, would be a good place to
start.” (para. 15)
He agreed that many mainstream economists, failed to foresee the globalization inevitably
leading to hyper globalization. He states that trade, even though not the main source of
increased economic inequality, has begun to contribute way more than anticipated in the
69
1990s. Specially the excessive imports from countries like Mexico and China where the
wages are only eleven and three percent, respectively, of the United States’ level have
proven to be detrimental to national economic equality. Although Krugman accepts this
dark side of hyper globalization, he still opposes protectionist policies as they will result in
closing the global markets to the poor nations in third world. Therefore, he claims that
‘labor standards’, allowing for unionizing and preventing slave and child labor, must be
inserted in free trade agreements with US. He even called out the Bush Administration for
not supporting the inclusion of these labor standards in trade agreements, as it might force
them to mend their own labor policies.
Krugman is skeptical that these amendments will positively affect the American
workers, as regardless of the labor autonomy to organize unions, the third world workers
will remain to earn lower wages. Hence, the wages in US will be forced to decrease. He
concludes that the mere amendments in trade policy are inadequate to achieve these goals.
There is a need for better pro-labor policies separate to the trade policy with a clause on
labor standards. One such policy would be to tax the winners in the economy and use that
to provide healthcare for all.
Krugman (2019) argued, that although the reliance on data for the correct
estimation of the modest impact of trade on relative wages was inevitable, the early 1990s
period was merely the beginning of the era of increasing trade flows. The volume and
nature of trade following the globalization eventually entered unlimited international
exchange flows. There was decrease in the cost of shipping overseas and eventually, the
capital was also freely mobile across borders. Subsequently, he would argue that the impact
70
of export producing countries was actually a lot more during the fifteen years following
1995 than they could anticipate in the 1990s consensus.
Krugman contended the backlash on globalization in the light of trade imbalances.
On contrary to his former pure mainstream approach, he later argued that ignoring trade
deficits due to their insignificant impact in long-run is not a well thought approach; as the
spiraling imports inflict a negative shock on the American manufacturing industry workers
in the short-run. For instance, after 2000, the manufacture goods deficit increased sharply
in the United States which resulted in a sharp decline in employment in manufacturing
industry. Therefore, the globalization has received such backlash in past years. Lastly,
Krugman (2007) admitted to his shortsightedness in ignoring the analytical methodologies
focused on workers in particular industries and communities would have better presented
the short-run trends. Hirsh (2019) recalled that “Krugman has been forthright in recent
years in second-guessing his earlier assertions about the effects of open trade.”
The 1990s consensus heavily relied on the models that presented the effects of trade
on unskilled or skilled labor and ended up concluding that trade did not significantly
contribute to rising inequality. Krugman’s tepid switch to the fair trade, also includes his
newly formed opinion on significance of having both winners and losers (Heckscher Ohlin
Model) resulting from trade and not merely looking at the overall increase in global
consumption.
Considering this switch in his stance, this thesis takes a stance that a staunch free
trade proponent like Krugman, after understanding the previously ignored fallacies of
hyper globalization, felt the need to redefine the role of government in trade policies. The
71
paper further favors the inculcation of fair trade clauses in trade agreements. In addition to
the effects of globalization not standing the test of time; the gender, labor and
environmental blindness of theories supporting trade liberalization calls for the need of fair
trade agreements. Essentially, the agreements based on fair trade will result in trade and
labor policy autonomy for developing countries who have been bonded by free trade
agreements with various countries in Global North. This can result in nations having proper
pro-labor policies complimented by trade policies to ensure prosperity. WTO and other
international financial institutions should facilitate these agreements between global
economies. Moreover, the countries will have the independence to explore, acknowledge
and prioritize their standards regarding labor, environment, race, and gender. Achieving
fair trade agreements based on cultural relativism will not only increase the overall
prosperity but will also help in achieving development on the basis of Sen’s (2000)
capabilities approach, and Marx’s ideal society thriving towards development and equality.
Hence, under fair trade regimes, the welfare state will aim towards immediate promotion
of true capabilities in all social groups resulting in overall growth of a nations involved in
trade flows.
3.3. Impacts of Trade Liberalization and Hyper Globalization
The international trade liberalization has carried significant expansion of economic
activities and driven the economic growth (not quite equally for the global north and south)
since the early 1980s, and so the climate injustice and demeaning labor standards have
prevailed at large scale. This sections provides facts regarding social and ecological
imbalances caused by adoption of above mentioned free trade doctrines.
72
3.3.1. Ecological Imbalances: Competing on Environmental Standards
The key energy injustice is the extreme over dependence of the global societies on
the use of fossil fuels to satisfy the expanding energy demand for the production and trade
of economic goods. According to the International Energy Agency, in 2016, the global
output production has doubled since the 1973. Since then (1973) the world only
experienced about 4% reduction (recorded in 2016) in the use of coal, oil and gases for the
energy production regardless of the advancement in high technology (McCauley, 2018).
The trends show that as the freedom of trade grew, the emissions carbon dioxide and other
harmful gases increases which led to the global climate change. Trade leads to very high
level of transport-related emissions, such as nitrogen dioxide form the motor vehicle
exhaustion. Trade liberalization requires increased transportation of goods, and in current
economy the capital mobility which contributes to hazardous wastes and toxins being
spilled into the environment. Not only increased global carbon emissions, but trade also
shifts their patterns. A very significant amount of carbon emissions has resulted from the
production of export goods for North America and Europe in China. The trade flows of
goods being produced in Global South and exported to Global North for consumption have
fair share in producing environmental externalities (Davis and Caldeira, 2010). This has
caused a differential impact of climate change on various groups.
Globally, the environment is bearing a heavy burnt of the climate change due to
substantial economic activity that the trade liberalization has stimulated. Some may
disagree, but the evidence from around the world, especially in China during the lockdown
73
during COVID-19, shows that heavy economic activity (mostly the production and
transportation of goods for export) contributed to bad air quality and harmful greenhouse
gases (GHGs) emissions. According to Caine (2020), almost half of the reduction in
nitrogen dioxide (which is emitted from the burning of fossil fuels) occurred as the heavy
industries in China were shut down amidst the lockdown. In short, we can find significant
evidence that the current global economic dynamics and trade liberalization has been
substantially impacting the environment adversely. We can assess the environmental
externalities of trade, the estimates of demand-based carbon emissions (final demand
distribution across economies for the embodied carbon emitted globally), using the OECD
Inter-Country Input-Output database combined with the carbon emissions by the burning
of fuel and industrial production across economies (Yamano & Guilhoto, 2020 and Wiebe
& Yamano, 2016).
China, Germany, India, Japan, Russia and United States are some of the leading
contributors to the carbon dioxide emissions in 2018 (OECD 2021). European Union (EU
27)
10
. The environmental externalities and the trade openness for China is the perfect
example of unaccounted trade flows considering the global climate. In 2018, three times
increase in the per capita demand for carbon emissions can be seen in China since 1995.
According to the International Energy Agency, China’s economic activity accounted for
approximately thirty percent of the global carbon emissions (2018). These carbon
emissions are caused by the combustion of energy related fossil fuels (IPCC 2013). In 2020,
10
Refers to twenty-seven European Union countries: Austria, Belgium, Bulgaria, Croatia, Republic of
Cyprus, Czech Republic, Denmark, Estonia, Finland, France, Germany, Greece, Hungary, Ireland, Italy,
Latvia, Lithuania, Luxembourg, Malta, Netherlands, Poland, Portugal, Romania, Slovakia, Slovenia, Spain
and Sweden.
74
China is emitting 10.67 billion out of 34.81 billion tonnes of total global carbon emissions
(Friedlingstein et al., 2022). To understand the relation between trade (open) to the climate
degradation we can look at China as an example.
Zheng et al. (2019) divides the history of China’s carbon emissions into three
stages: First, the launch of reform and opening up (2000) where the carbon emissions were
increasing slowly at 4.2%; second, becoming the part of WTO (2001) and the emissions
were growing at the annual rate of 8.5%; and finally, where the emissions rate was growing
at 0.81%. The period after China joined WTO experienced high carbon emissions as the
industrial production increased significantly in response to the trade openness. After 2001,
there was openness to trade without any restrictions, so China’s investment increased
significantly in the energy-intensive industrial production and therefore the world
experienced the sharp increase in environmental externalities due to combustion of fossil
fuels for the purpose of energy consumption. On the other hand, the OECD countries are
the net importers of the embodied carbon emissions. Although the share of United State of
America in global carbon emissions is less than a half of that of China, it remains one of
the highest consumer of embodied carbon emissions. In 2019, United States’ net import of
carbon dioxide was approximately 7% higher than its net exports (Andrew and Peters
2021). Many other countries, for instance Japan and Germany, from the Global North are
highly contributing to the climate injustice. According to Harris and Roach (2013), a
significant portion of emissions are resulting from the production in Global South (China)
to be exported to and consumed in Global North (United States and Europe). There is a
separation of cost and benefits of the negative externalities which results in high inequality
75
around the globe. Resulting in the proposition that trade patterns have extremely important
implications for negotiations at the international level.
The intensive combustion of fossil fuels for heavy industrial productions to
compete in open trading system has had immense adverse impact on the climate. There is
a need to rework the doctrines of trade around the global (specially between global south
and north) to reduce inequality and differential impact of climate change. These climate
change evidences have resulted in wide ranging contentions against the trade openness by
the environmentalists (World Commission on Environment and Development, 1987).
Some economists argue that the economic growth and development can be achieved rather
sustainably along with improving environmental conditions. One such policy is “fair
trade”. Fair trade is a model that seeks equity in international trade. This fair-trade
approach’s theoretical groundwork is based on “harmonization of capabilities at a level that
is sufficient, universally attainable and sustainable” (DeMartino 2002). This thesis will
look at the impact of implementing fair trade policies on the environmental externalities
and climate change.
3.3.2. Social Imbalances: Competing on Labor Standards and Safety
The phenomenon of capital mobility, which has emerged as a result of the process
of hyper globalization, has been extensively noted to have led to the outsourcing of
inexpensive labor by large corporations in the global south. According to Davidson et al.
(2007), in order to compete on a global scale, reduced production costs are utilized through
the implementation of lower wages and substandard working conditions. Furthermore, as
76
per Cooney's (1998) analysis, the International Labor Organization (ILO) has exhibited a
significant lack of efficacy in countering the escalating influence of transnational
corporations on a global scale. The author posits that the primary cause is attributed to
inadequate enforcement capabilities. The fair traders argue that it is crucial to establish
enduring objectives aimed at restructuring the bargaining power of labor and capital
owners. This necessitates the involvement of national governments in fair trade
agreements, thereby exercising their autonomy.
Mazzucato (2018) deftly recalls the debate over such limited and quantitative
measurement, as well as, more importantly, the generation of value in the economy. She
notes that the economic debate on value has mostly focused on price while disregarding
the history of economic thought on production and wealth distribution. She thinks that
environmental, labor, and poverty legislation should be more than just supplements to
policymaking. Instead, these factors should be key to evaluating today's value metrics, such
as GDP and, by extension, economic growth. To do this, it is even more necessary to
negotiate an international agreement to ensure that countries that meet minimum
environmental, labor, and other standards are not discriminated against in the global value
chain. Improvements in both environmental and labor conditions are crucial to attaining
sustainable development, in which current economic development efforts take into account
resource availability and the standard of living of future generations (Krugman, 2011).
As production has shifted to global south, fair traders have raised concerns
regarding the working conditions and labor standards in developing economies. .
Globalization and the spread of industry supply chains to developing nations have sparked
a heated debate over how to improve labor standards in these emerging production centers
77
(Locke & Romis, 2007). There is a growing realization that low labor standards in
developing countries can lead to a race to the bottom, in which big corporations seek out
the lowest-cost production locations regardless of labor standards. The issue of child labor,
hazardous work environments, prolonged working schedules, and inadequate remuneration
are enduring challenges in numerous production hubs situated in developing nations. The
aforementioned concerns have led to disputes and instances of discomfiture for large
corporations that make use of said amenities.
Numerous academic studies have provided evidence of the prevalence of such
challenges in workplaces located in developing nations. The prevalence of child labor in
factories across Bangladesh, China, and India has been documented by Connor and Dent's
(2005) research. Additionally, hazardous working conditions have been observed in
various industries in countries such as China, Bangladesh, and Indonesia. As per
Kernaghan's (2006) findings, instances of prolonged working hours and inadequate
remuneration were observed in industrial sectors situated in China and Mexico (Lazare,
2006). These issues have resulted due to worldwide competitive forces, which can prompt
the implementation of cost-reduction tactics that culminate in unfavorable labor conditions
and inadequate remuneration for workers (Elson and Pearson, 1981; Kabeer 2004). In many
developing countries, the implementation of labor laws and regulations by local
governments is often hindered by insufficient resources and a lack of political
determination, thereby perpetuating these problems.
Consequently, there has been a surge in demands by fair traders for multinational
corporations to assume accountability for the labor conditions prevalent in the factories
where their merchandise is produced. Numerous enterprises have established codes of
78
conduct and monitoring mechanisms to tackle these concerns. However, detractors argue
that these endeavors have been insufficient in addressing the magnitude of the issue. In
light of the constrained ability of numerous governments in developing countries to
implement their labor regulations (Baccaro, 2001; Elliott and Freeman, 2003),
multinational corporations have established their own "codes of conduct" (Scharge, 2004;
Mamic, 2004) for their suppliers, along with diverse monitoring mechanisms designed to
ensure adherence to these codes. The statement pertains to the incapacity of several
governments in developing nations to perform the aforementioned task, as noted by
Baccaro (2001) and Elliott and Freeman (2003). Locke and Romis (2007) assert that global
corporations and labor rights nongovernmental organizations rely on compliance checks as
the primary approach to addressing poor working conditions in manufacturers within the
global supply chain. Though not official, the objective is to ensure that factories adhere to
their respective codes of conduct. However, various free traders express their obliviousness
towards importance of fair trade policy measures negotiated by international organizations
such as WTO, IMF and WB. Evidently, the women in question aspire to enhance their
working conditions. Kabeer (2008) explains the dilemma of exploited women in
manufacturing industries in global south, due to the absence of a social safety net, is
cognizant of the fact that their sole alternative, employment in the informal sector, is
significantly inferior. Consequently, they are precluded from advocating for improved
labor standards. Efforts to enforce labor standards globally via trade sanctions may result
in the displacement or relocation of jobs to the informal sector. In the absence of measures
to enhance the circumstances of laborers in the private sector, the imposition of "the social
clause" may exacerbate social disparities in the labor market.
79
Notwithstanding the casual nature of these codes with regards to authorized trade
agreements, advocates of equitable trade and societal activists in the developed world have
contended that there are "inequitable" labor practices and circumstances in the trading
partners of developing countries that require suitable trade policy measures to "equalize the
opportunities." The present thesis endeavors to argue in favor of a fair trade system that
can establish a "level playing field." There is a concern that the augmented imports from
nations where labor standards are purportedly not enforced at an adequate level may have
an adverse impact on the remuneration and labor conditions in the industrialized importing
nations. There is a contention that laborers in emerging nations are susceptible to
exploitative and oppressive labor circumstances, and that their remuneration is repressed.
3.5 Conclusion
The significance of trade has garnered considerable attention from economists,
policy experts, government officials, and the public, on a global scale, and this attention
definitely holds a strong merit. During the postwar era, and particularly in recent decades,
there has been a gradual rise in the proportion of worldwide economic activity that can be
ascribed to trade. Furthermore, during the 1990s, trade negotiators hailing from both the
Northern and Southern hemispheres collaborated to develop expansive trade accords. The
aforementioned accords have considerably facilitated the liberalization of the transnational
flow of goods, services, and capital.
The creation of the World Trade Organization (WTO) as a result of the negotiations
held during the Uruguay Round of discussions on the General Agreement on Tariffs and
80
Trade (GATT) is considered the most extensive among the various agreements. This
agreement was achieved shortly after the implementation of the North American Free
Trade Agreement (NAFTA), which aimed to fully deregulate trade across North America
within the subsequent ten years. The North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA)
was ultimately ratified by the governments of the United States, Canada, and Mexico,
despite encountering substantial opposition within each country.
It is noteworthy that in 1997, a mere three years subsequent to the ratification of the
North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA), President Clinton encountered an
inability to secure congressional endorsement for fast-track authorization (DeMartino,
2000). The aforementioned authorization would have enabled the administration in
question to engage in negotiations aimed at extending the stipulations of the North
American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) to additional countries situated in the Latin
American region. This occurrence of failure transpired a mere three years subsequent to
the ratification of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA). The World Trade
Organization (WTO) has faced notable criticism, especially in the Southern regions, where
farmers have expressed opposition to the organization's potential social and economic
impacts. Despite the ongoing progress towards complete economic integration, various
factions globally such as labor associations, have expressed notable apprehension
regarding the character and consequences of neoliberal unification.
81
Chapter 4: How Free Are "FTAs"? Evidence of Government Intervention
4.1 Introduction
Free trade agreements (FTAs) have been a topic of controversy since their
inception. Advocates argue that they enhance market accessibility and commercial activity,
thereby stimulating economic growth and employment opportunities. FTAs aim to
facilitate international trade by removing tariffs and non-tariff barriers. The outcome is
expected to be a result of competition, lower prices for consumers, and the advancement
of the economy. Nevertheless, detractors argue that FTAs exhibit a lack of impartiality and
instead provide preferential treatment to prominent corporations and affluent nations at the
expense of emerging nations and small enterprises (Rodrik, 2018).
Nonetheless, several FTAs comprise clauses that safeguard specific sectors or
nations, a practice that some contend contravenes the principles of unrestricted commerce.
Several FTAs containing patent and copyright clauses that provide advantages to big
corporations at the expense of small enterprises and emerging economies are discussed in
this chapter. Moreover, FTAs have the potential to result in job losses within non-
competitive industries. The potential negative impact on the local economy and workforce
is also a matter of concern by fair traders.
The chapter validates the criticism on FTAs on the grounds that they do not adhere
to the principles of free trade, as they offer protection to specific businesses or countries.
For instance, the Central America-Dominican Republic Free Trade
82
Agreement (CAFTA-DR) safeguards the interests of American pharmaceutical
enterprises, whereas the US-Korea Free Trade Agreement (KORUS FTA) safeguards the
interests of American automobile manufacturers. This phenomenon could potentially
confer advantages upon certain enterprises or countries while hindering the principles of
free trade.
It is widely believed that FTAs exhibit a bias towards larger corporations and
industrialized nations at the expense of smaller enterprises and developing countries
(Warren, 2015). While larger organizations possess the necessary resources to take
advantage of FTA opportunities, smaller enterprises may lack the means to do so. FTA
have the potential to displace small businesses in underdeveloped countries that lack the
resources to compete with multinational corporations given the lack of transparency in
dispute settlements (Hahm et al., 2019). Further, they have the potential to result in adverse
effects such as unemployment and negative externalities stemming from heightened
economic activity. This chapter provides evidence that free trade policies never actually
adhere to the notion of “free.” The state intervention to safeguard the rights of developed
nations and big corporations is one of the biggest instance of protection in these so called
“free trade agreements.”
4.2 Brief History of North American Free Trade Agreements
Since, the United States of America holds a crucial position in the global economy,
rendering it a significant case for analysis in the context of world trade activities, it is
reasonable to begin with a discussion of its role in FTAs. The United States harbors some
of the most prominent multinational corporations worldwide, exerting significant influence
83
in shaping global trade dynamics, and it has taken a prominent role in advancing free trade
policies and accords, exemplified by initiatives such as the North American Free Trade
Agreement (NAFTA) and the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP). After the end of World War
II, the US government took a leading role in promoting the ideals of free trade and creating
international institutions to facilitate its implementation. Chang (2002) recalls that:
“It was only after World War II, with its industrial
supremacy unchallenged, that the United States liberalized
its trade and started championing the cause of free trade
once again proving List right on his "ladder-kicking"
metaphor. However, it should be noted that the United States
never practiced free trade to the same degree as Britain did
during its free-trade period (1860 – 1932).” (p. 85)
From 1947 until 1994, the world was bound by the multilateral pact known as the
General pact on Tariffs and Trade (GATT)
11
. Its purpose is to facilitate international
commerce by lowering trade barriers such as tariffs. In the years after World War II, GATT
was essential in reshaping the international trading system and the whole global economy.
GATT underwent eight rounds of negotiations, each of which was designated as a "round"
and assigned a sequential number (Crowley, 2003). The Kennedy Round, a trade
negotiation that spanned from 1964 to 1967, yielded a noteworthy outcome of a 35%
decrease in tariffs (La Barca, 2016). The Tokyo Round, a multilateral trade negotiation
spanning from 1973 to 1979, is notable for its incorporation of non-tariff barriers into the
negotiation framework (Coppolaro, 2018 and Gilbert, 1986).
11
See WTO:
https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/gatt_e/gatt_e.htm#:~:text=The%20General%20Agreement%20on%2
0Tariffs,from%20all%20WTO%20member%20countries
For detail analysis of its principles see: Wolf (1987), Baldwin (1987) and Bhagwati (1990 and 1991)
84
The Tokyo Round facilitated the subsequent Uruguay Round, which yielded
extensive outcomes and significantly advanced the global economic integration
(Coppolaro, 2018). The Uruguay Round, which took place from 1986 to 1994, was a
comprehensive and ambitious series of negotiations that resulted in the creation of the
World Trade Organization (WTO) (Zeiler, 2012). The principal aims of the Uruguay
Round were to reduce tariffs and non-tariff barriers, improve market access for services,
and strengthen the protection of intellectual property rights. Subsequent to the formation
of the WTO, GATT remained a binding agreement until 1995, when it was replaced by the
Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) under the
auspices of the WTO
12
(Kennedy, 2015 and Correa, 2007). The inclusion of TRIPs in the
Uruguay Round, however, was opposed by many fervent free-trade advocates (Bhagwati,
Krishna, and Panagariya 2014). Currently, the WTO remains the primary global
organization tasked with the responsibility of supervising international trade and resolving
trade-related disputes.
Furthermore, the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) was ratified in
1994 amongst the United States, Canada, and Mexico
13
. The elimination of trade barriers
and promotion of unrestricted movement of goods, services, and investments between the
three nations was facilitated by this agreement (Hakobyan and McLaren, 2016). NAFTA
was the inaugural trade agreement between industrialized and emerging nations, and it had
a notable influence on the economic conditions of the participating nations (Romalis,
12
See WTO: https://www.wto.org/english/thewto_e/thewto_e.htm
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/issue-areas/trade-organizations/world-trade-organization-wto
13
See USTR Archives: https://ustr.gov/about-us/policy-offices/press-office/ustr-archives/north-american-
free-trade-agreement-nafta
85
2007). Several significant provisions of NAFTA comprised the removal of tariffs on
numerous commodities, the expansion of service markets, and the safeguarding of
intellectual property privileges. Another FTA, United Stated-Jordan Free Trade
Agreements, followed in 2000
14
.
In 2004, United States signed The Dominican Republic-Central America-United
States Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA-DR) with Costa Rica, the Dominican Republic, El
Salvador, Guatemala, Honduras, and Nicaragua
15
. The objective of the agreement was to
enhance the trade and investment activities within the member nations. The agreement
encompassed clauses pertaining to agriculture, textiles, and services. The inclusion of
intellectual property provisions in CAFTA-DR was a contentious issue due to the
perception that such provisions favored US industries over those of the other participating
nations (Castro, 2015). Several other FTAs followed the CAFTA-DR
16
.
Successively, the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) was a significant trade
agreement that involved the United States and was signed in 2016 by twelve countries in
the Asia-Pacific region
17
. After the inauguration of the Trump administration, the United
States opted to withdraw from the aforementioned agreement in 2017 (Riley, 2017). The
Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) had the objective of diminishing tariffs and other
14
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/trade-agreements/free-trade-agreements/jordan-fta
15
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/trade-agreements/free-trade-agreements/cafta-dr-dominican-republic-central-
america-fta
16
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/trade-agreements/free-trade-agreements
2004: United States-Australia Free Trade Agreement
2005: United States-Chile Free Trade Agreement
2006: United States-Oman Free Trade Agreement
2007: United States-Peru Trade Promotion Agreement
2011: United States-Korea Free Trade Agreement (KORUS FTA)
2012: United States-Colombia Trade Promotion Agreement
17
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/trade-agreements/free-trade-agreements/trans-pacific-partnership/tpp-full-text
86
impediments to trade, enhancing labor and environmental safeguards, and encouraging
investment within the participating nations.
Ultimately, the United States, Canada, and Mexico entered into an agreement in
2018 known as the United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA) as a replacement
for the NAFTA
18
. The accord encompasses clauses pertaining to workforce and ecology,
alongside revised safeguards for intellectual property. The revised agreement entails
significant modifications such as the imposition of elevated thresholds for the proportion
of North American content that must be met by specific products to be eligible for
exemption from tariffs, the establishment of fresh regulations of origin for automobiles,
and the expansion of the Canadian dairy market to US farmers (Lea, 2018 and Norman,
2018).
4.3 Government Intervention in Provisions of the Free Trade Agreements
Notwithstanding the label "free trade," governmental intervention has been quite
evident in free trade agreements. This section examines various methods through which
governments have intervened in Free Trade Agreements (FTAs).
4.3.1. Intellectual Property Rights (IPRs)
Incorporation of clauses pertaining to intellectual property rights (IPR) or property
rights is a common practice in trade agreements within the United States trade and
investment framework (Dur et al., 2014). IPRs in FTAs have strengthened over time. FTAs
18
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/trade-agreements/free-trade-agreements/united-states-mexico-canada-
agreement
87
initially eliminated tariffs and quotas, however, later, trade agreements required to address
IPRs in the information economy. Developed nations desired IPRs in FTAs to safeguard
their pharmaceutical, software, and music industries. NAFTA, signed in 1994, protected
IPR
19
. NAFTA covered copyrights, trademarks, patents, and trade secrets. The 1995 WTO
Agreement on Trade-Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights (TRIPS) also added
comparable portions
20
. The TRIPS agreement encompasses three primary domains of
intellectual property rights, namely patents, copyrights, and trademarks. It lays down
fundamental principles that regulate intellectual property rights, such as national treatment
and most-favored nation, and also sets out the minimum standards for IPRs and their
enforcement (Osgood and Feng, 2017). The 2004 CAFTA-DR
21
, 2012 KORUS
22
and 2016
TPP
23
FTA included stricter IPR protections. These parts addressed piracy, counterfeiting,
copyright protection for digital material, and longer medication patents. In 2020, USMCA
replaced NAFTA with intellectual property responsibilities
24
. USMCA protects patents,
copyrights, and trademarks. The USMCA also prohibits online piracy and counterfeiting
and ensures adequate intellectual property infringement sanctions.
FTA IPRs are blamed for impeding access to crucial pharmaceuticals and other
improvements. Strong IPR restrictions benefit industrialized countries' firms and hinder
emerging nations' access to breakthrough technology. In conclusion, industrialized nations
19
See OAS: http://www.sice.oas.org/trade/nafta/chap-172.asp#A1714
20
See WTO: https://www.wto.org/english/tratop_e/trips_e/trips_e.htm
21
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/uploads/agreements/cafta/asset_upload_file934_3935.pdf
22
See USTR:
https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/uploads/agreements/fta/korus/asset_upload_file273_12717.pdf
23
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/TPP-Final-Text-Intellectual-Property.pdf
24
See USTR comparison of NAFTA and USMCA:
https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/files/Press/fs/USMCA/USMCA_IP.pdf
88
have sought greater safeguards, increasing IPRs in FTAs. FTA IPRs are contentious
because to worries regarding innovation and pharmaceutical availability IPRs have
evolved. FTAs initially eliminated tariffs and quotas. Trade agreements required to address
IPRs in the information economy. Developed nations desired IPRs in FTAs to safeguard
their pharmaceutical, software, and music industries.
The inclusion of property rights clauses in trade agreements in the United States is
based on the belief that strong and enforceable protections for intellectual property are
essential for promoting innovation, creativity, and investment, as well as fostering
economic growth and progress (Richards., 2002 and 2004). The provisions typically define
the scope, duration, and enforcement mechanisms for intellectual property rights, and may
also include provisions related to technology transfer, disclosure of information, and
dispute resolution. Proponents of strong intellectual property rights embedded in trade
agreements argue that they are essential for promoting innovation, protecting investments
in research and development, and ensuring fair conditions for business enterprises.
According to the proponents, these clauses are consistent with international agreements
and standards, and could promote the development of innovative concepts and economic
growth.
25
The inclusion of robust intellectual property rights (IPRs) clauses within free trade
agreements (FTAs) can be perceived as a manifestation of state intervention in so called
“free trade”. The implementation of intellectual property rights (IPRs) via trade agreements
represents a deviation from the conventional free trade doctrine (Smith, 1776; Ricardo,
25
See (Kim, 2015), (Kim et al., 2016) and (Manger and Shadlen, 2014)
89
1817), which advocates for the advancement of competition and innovation by enabling
unrestricted movement of commodities and amenities across national boundaries
(Bhagwati, 2007). This thesis delineates that rather than fostering innovation, the practice
in question seeks to establish legal monopolies or oligopolies that curtail competition and
impede the advancement of novel products and technologies, particularly in emerging
economies. The aforementioned intervention confers advantages to the corporations that
possess the patents or copyrights. However, it may have deleterious effects on consumers
by augmenting prices and restricting access to indispensable medicines, technologies, and
cultural products.
Notwithstanding the potential benefits of strong intellectual property rights,
detractors raise concerns about their potential negative impact on the availability of
pharmaceuticals, diffusion of technology, and the ability of developing countries to attain
their developmental goals. The argument put forth is that overly strict regulations on
intellectual property may hinder the availability of affordable medications, limit market
competition, and hinder the ability of developing countries to adopt and adapt technologies
for their economic progress.
The incorporation of IPRs in the US-Jordan Free Trade Agreement
26
led to elevated
costs, postponed introduction of generic pharmaceuticals and drugs, as noted by Abbott et
al. (2012). According to Alawi and Alabbadi (2015), data exclusivity has resulted in a
restriction on the accessibility of generic drugs and medications. According to Kyle and
McGahan's (2012) research, the implementation of patent protection for Research and
26
See USTR:
https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/uploads/agreements/fta/jordan/asset_upload_file120_8462.pdf
90
Development (R&D) has resulted in an increase of R&D activities in developed countries,
while the same cannot be said for developing countries. The study conducted by Shaffer
and Brenner (2009) investigated the drug availability in Guatemala subsequent to the
rigorous enforcement of Intellectual Property Rights (IPRs). The findings revealed a
decrease in the accessibility of existing generic drugs and a delay in the importation of new
generic drugs. In short, the prediction of limited medication accessibility by all pre
implementation of IPR studies turned out to be an expected outcome (Trachtenberg et al.,
2019).
4.3.2. Investor-State Dispute Settlement (ISDS)
The inclusion of the Investor-State Dispute Settlement (ISDS) mechanism has been
observed in multiple Free Trade Agreements (FTAs) that have been ratified by the United
States. The eleventh chapter of the North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA)
includes provisions for Investor-State Dispute Settlement (ISDS)
27
. According to Article
1101
28
, the chapter's scope is defined as follows: an investor belonging to a Party is entitled
to present a claim to arbitration under this Section, alleging that the other Party has violated
specific obligations. The definition of "investment" and "investor", obligation of fair and
equitable treatment, and minimum standard of treatment is established in subsequent
chapters.
27
See OAS: http://www.sice.oas.org/trade/nafta/chap-111.asp#Chap.XI
28
See: http://www.sice.oas.org/trade/nafta/chap-111.asp#A1101
91
Similarly, Chapter 11, Section B
29
of the United States-Korea Free Trade
Agreement (KORUS FTA) encompasses ISDS provisions. The chapter's scope is
established by Article 11.1, which pertains to investments made by investors from one
party within the jurisdiction of the other party. Chapter 9, Section B
30
of the Trans-Pacific
Partnership (TPP) agreement also incorporates provisions pertaining to ISDS. The
chapter's scope, as stipulated in Article 9.1, pertains to investments made by investors
belonging to the TPP member states. Likewise, the fourteenth chapter
31
of the United
States-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA) incorporates ISDS provisions, albeit with
certain modifications as compared to the NAFTA.
It is noteworthy that the ISDS provisions have been a subject of controversy and
have encountered censure from diverse sources. The ISDS mechanism has garnered
significant interest from both scholars and the public, necessitating a thorough analysis
(Hahm et al., 2019). Rodrik (2018) explains that ISDS is not immune to challenges as it
operates beyond established legal frameworks, grants excessive authority to arbitrators,
lacks adherence to or establishment of legal precedents, and precludes the possibility of
appeal. The inclusion of ISDS in trade agreements among advanced countries with well-
functioning legal systems, is more challenging to justify, despite its potential benefits for
developing nations. It is due to their perceived capacity to erode national sovereignty and
exhibit partiality towards multinational corporations at the expense of domestic enterprises.
Stiglitz (2015) expounds that:
29
See USTR:
https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/uploads/agreements/fta/korus/Chapter_Eleven_Investment.pdf
30
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/TPP-Final-Text-Investment.pdf
31
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/files/agreements/FTA/USMCA/Text/14-Investment.pdf
92
“International corporate interests tout ISDS as necessary to
protect property rights where the rule of law and credible
courts are lacking. But that argument is nonsense. The US is
seeking the same mechanism in a similar mega-deal with the
European Union, the Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership, even though there is little question about the
quality of Europe’s legal and judicial systems.
To be sure, investors wherever they call home deserve
protection from expropriation or discriminatory regulations.
But ISDS goes much further: The obligation to compensate
investors for losses of expected profits can and has been
applied even where rules are nondiscriminatory, and profits
are made from causing public harm.” (para. 8-9)
In short, trade and investment agreements offer foreign investors expanded
property protection rights that surpass those enshrined in domestic constitutions.
32
The
aforementioned entitlements are conferred via agreements pertaining to trade and
investment.
4.3.3. Government Procurement (GP)
The method through which governments purchase goods and services for internal
use is known as government procurement, and it is covered under several FTAs. Chapter
10
33
of the NAFTA laid out the rules and regulations that were to govern government
procurement throughout the three member countries with the aim of promoting greater
levels of transparency and fairness throughout the procurement process. In particular, it
mandated that each member nation should treat suppliers of goods and services from the
other members equally and without discrimination. Discrimination against suppliers from
32
See Corporate Europe Observatory: https://corporateeurope.org/en/international-trade/2014/04/still-not-
loving-isds-10-reasons-oppose-investors-super-rights-eu-trade
33
See OAS: http://www.sice.oas.org/trade/nafta/chap-101.asp#Chap.X
93
other member nations is prohibited under Article 1001. The need that all members provide
one another "national treatment" in terms of government procurement is one of Chapter
10's most significant provisions. This means that all bidders from each member nation must
be treated equally with respect to the procurement process and are not permitted to be the
target of discriminatory or protectionist activities. While Article 1003 mandates that every
member state promptly publish its procurement policies and regulations.
Similarly, the provisions pertaining to government procurement in the CAFTA-
DR
34
mandate that all participating nations must extend equitable treatment to suppliers of
goods and services from other participating nations during their government procurement
procedures, with certain exceptions. The aforementioned pertains to the acquisition of
commodities and amenities by federal establishments, state-owned corporations, and sub-
national entities. Within the framework of CAFTA-DR, member nations are obligated to
disclose their procurement opportunities, along with the standards and methodologies
employed to assess proposals, with the aim of promoting impartiality and openness in the
procurement procedure. Notwithstanding, specific exclusions are applicable to particular
government procurement undertakings, including those associated with safeguarding
national security, promoting public health, or preserving cultural heritage.
Likewise, chapter 17 of the US-Korea Free Trade Agreement (KORUS) contains
rules for public procurement
35
. Each member nation is required to provide suppliers of
products and services from the other member nation fair and transparent procurement
34
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/uploads/agreements/cafta/asset_upload_file766_3926.pdf
35
See USTR:
https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/uploads/agreements/fta/korus/asset_upload_file2_12716.pdf
94
procedures. Article 15.2 states that each member nation must promptly publicize its
procurement policies and regulations and forbids discrimination against vendors from the
other member countries. Furthermore, government procurement is also covered in Chapter
13
36
of the USMCA and Chapter 15
37
of TPP. Under these provisions each member nation
is required to provide suppliers of products and services from the other member nation fair
and transparent procurement procedures. Article 13.2 of USMCA specifically states that
each member nation must promptly publicize its procurement policies and regulations and
forbids discrimination against vendors from the other member countries.
Critics claim that these clauses might hurt domestic businesses and result in the
privatization of public services. For instance, the government procurement clauses in FTAs
have come under fire for giving foreign companies access to government contracts at the
cost of domestic firms and employees. Upon conducting a comprehensive analysis, it can
be inferred that if emerging economies were to grant market access in government
procurement, they would relinquish their authority over a crucial policy instrument for
development (Sengupta, 2012). Sengupta suggests that developing nations may only be
required to adhere to transparency measures outlined in the GP provisions of their Free
Trade Agreements, without any additional obligations. Despite the prevalent lack of
transparency and corruption in several developing political and economic systems, along
with significant gaps in the implementation of development-friendly GP policy, it is
imperative for developing nations to address these issues domestically while preserving the
36
See USTR:
https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/files/agreements/FTA/USMCA/Text/13_Government_Procurement.pdf
37
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/TPP-Final-Text-Government-Procurement.pdf
95
flexibility and significance of this policy tool. Particularly talking about the prospects of
GP provisions in India’s FTAs, Sengupta (2012) declares:
“It is important again to emphasize that India can always
invite global bids on a need basis as it does currently without
making legal commitments to do so. India should not be
giving up development-sensitive policy tools for very
dubious gains in return.” (p. 22)
Additionally, some contend that these clauses may lead to a race to the bottom in
which governments slacken labor laws and regulations to draw in foreign investment.
Furthermore, a lot of people think that the laws and regulations described in the chapter
have actually made the procurement process extremely difficult for smaller businesses to
navigate, giving larger organizations an advantage.
4.3.4 Regulatory Cooperation
The regulatory cooperation provisions incorporated in free trade agreements
(FTAs) are intended to facilitate the standardization of regulations and standards across the
nations involved, with the objective of mitigating trade impediments and fostering
economic amalgamation. For instance, chapter 25
38
of the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP)
was designed to foster collaboration and synchronization among member nations in the
formulation and execution of regulatory measures, as part of its overarching objective. The
promotion of regulatory cooperation to facilitate trade and investment among member
countries was specifically mandated by Article 25.1. Similarly, the KORUS Free Trade
Agreement contained a section dedicated to Technical Barriers to Trade, specifically
38
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/TPP-Final-Text-Regulatory-Coherence.pdf
96
outlined in Chapter 7
39
. This chapter encompassed various provisions pertaining to
regulatory cooperation. The establishment of a Regulatory Cooperation Council, as stated
in Article 7.10, aims to promote cooperation and coordination between regulatory
authorities in both countries.
Moreover, the United States has signed other FTAs that incorporate regulatory
cooperation provisions, such as the USMCA. The Regulatory Cooperation chapter
(Chapter 28)
40
within the USMCA outlines a structured framework for collaboration on
regulatory matters, encompassing the formulation of uniform strategies to address
regulatory concerns and the exchange of optimal methodologies.
In general, the provisions pertaining to regulatory cooperation within Free Trade
Agreements (FTAs) are a contentious issue and are prone to receiving critical feedback.
Although regional trade agreements with regulatory provisions have the potential to
decrease trade barriers and encourage economic integration, they are most likely to result
in the dilution of significant health, safety, and environmental regulations, as well as the
exertion of substantial corporate influence on the regulatory framework (Schmidt, 2009).
4.3.5. Anticorruption Provisions
Generally, as per the federal legislation of the United States, engaging in corrupt
activities, such as bribery, by multinational corporations or other entities with the intention
of obtaining contracts is considered illegal. The Foreign Corrupt Practices Act (FCPA)
41
is
39
See USTR:
https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/uploads/agreements/fta/korus/asset_upload_file604_12708.pdf
40
See USTR:
https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/files/agreements/FTA/USMCA/Text/28_Good_Regulatory_Practices.pdf
41
See Dept. of Justice: https://www.justice.gov/criminal-fraud/foreign-corrupt-practices-act
97
a federal statute that was enacted in 1977. The regulation stipulates that U.S. corporations,
foreign corporations that are publicly traded on U.S. stock exchanges, and individuals and
organizations acting on behalf of said corporations are prohibited from participating in acts
of corruption. The aforementioned legislation forbids the offering of any type of
remuneration or advantage to officials of foreign governments, political organizations, or
aspirants for the purpose of acquiring or retaining commercial advantages.
Particular to the FTAs, the objective of anticorruption provisions is to mitigate and
counteract corrupt activities in both public and private domains, enhance openness and
answerability, and foster principled commercial conduct in trade agreements. For instance,
the anticorruption provisions of CAFTA-DR necessitate that every party involved must
criminalize bribery and embezzlement and implement measures to prevent and identify
corruption in the public sector
42
. The agreement encompasses measures aimed at fostering
transparency in governmental procurement, safeguarding individuals who report illegal or
unethical activities, and strengthening collaboration among the signatories to prevent and
counteract corrupt practices.
In addition to the aforementioned, the Trans-Pacific Partnership's (TPP) anti-
corruption chapter encompasses clauses mandating the criminalization of bribery and
embezzlement, and necessitates that each participating nation implement or uphold
measures aimed at preventing and identifying corruption within the public sector
43
. The
aforementioned text encompasses measures aimed at fostering transparency in the realm
of public procurement, bolstering collaboration among involved parties to prevent and
42
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/uploads/agreements/cafta/asset_upload_file294_3938.pdf
43
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/TPP-Final-Text-Transparency-and-Anti-corruption.pdf
98
combat instances of corruption, and instituting protocols for managing situations involving
potential conflicts of interest.
The recently ratified United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA) includes
an anticorruption chapter that mandates the criminalization of bribery of public officials
and individuals involved in business activities, as well as the implementation of
preventative measures to detect and deter such illicit behavior
44
. The document additionally
encompasses clauses aimed at advancing transparency in governmental purchasing
processes, reinforcing safeguards for individuals who report misconduct, and augmenting
collaboration among involved entities to forestall and counteract corrupt practices.
These provisions are expected to have positive impact on the trade agreements,
however, the implementation of anti-corruption provisions within FTAs can present
difficulties stemming from challenges related to enforcement, transparency, cultural
nuances, intricacy, aversion to change, and inadequate coordination. Overcoming these
obstacles necessitates a persistent endeavor from all parties concerned. As issues
concerning the jurisprudence of allegations of corruption in investment arbitration have
been the subject of extensive discussion in economic policies, there have been relatively
few studies conducted on the increasing practices of anti-corruption provisions (Yan,
2022). In particular, there is a lack of a methodology for extensively assessing the driving
reasons and expectations of anti-corruption measures in the present inventory of IIAs.
44
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/files/agreements/FTA/USMCA/Text/27_Anticorruption.pdf
99
4.3.6. Social and Ecological Provisions
Numerous primary free trade agreements (FTAs) entered into by the United States
of America incorporate provisions pertaining to social and ecological considerations, such
as labor rights, safeguarding the environment, and promoting sustainable development.
Chapter 23
45
of the United States-Mexico-Canada Agreement (USMCA) encompasses
provisions pertaining to labor, such as the elimination of forced labor and the entitlement
to engage in collective bargaining. Furthermore, Chapter 24 comprises stipulations that are
linked to the ecosystem. The aforementioned provisions encompass commitments to
maintain compliance with environmental regulations and ensure the protection of
biodiversity
46
.
In the same vein, chapter 19 of the Trans-Pacific Partnership (TPP) encompasses
provisions pertaining to labor, which entail the proscription of child and forced labor, as
well as the capacity to participate in collective bargaining
47
. Although Chapter 20
48
incorporates certain provisions pertaining to the environment, including obligations to
safeguard endangered species and combat illicit fishing and logging, Sachs (2015)
delineates that these provisions are:
“A set of standards on labor and environment that purport to
advance the cause of social fairness and environmental
sustainability. But the agreements are thin, unenforceable
and generally unimaginative. For example, climate change
is not even mentioned, much less addressed boldly and
creatively.” (para. 7)
45
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/files/agreements/FTA/USMCA/Text/23%20Labor.pdf
46
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/files/agreements/usmca/24_Environment.pdf
47
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/TPP-Final-Text-Labour.pdf
48
See USTR: https://ustr.gov/sites/default/files/TPP-Final-Text-Environment.pdf
100
Detractors of these clauses contend that they lack the necessary efficacy to uphold
social and ecological standards, and that they may be undermined by the ISDS (Investor-
State Dispute Settlement) mechanism and other policies that prioritize corporate interests
(Johnson, Sachs and Sachs, 2016). This argument posits that the aforementioned provisions
may be invalidated by other provisions that prioritize corporate interests. Moreover, there
is a perspective held by certain economists that suggest the utilization of these clauses by
affluent nations as a means of imposing their norms upon less developed nations, rather
than fostering authentic sustainable development and equitable social outcomes (Bhagwati,
2007). This constitutes an additional argument posited by certain individuals.
One potential motivation for domestic industries to advocate for the inclusion of
labor and environmental standards in trade agreements is to protect themselves from
competition with inexpensive imports that may be perceived as having an unfair advantage
due to less stringent labor and environmental regulations. This concern stems from the fear
that such imports could be subsidized, leading to a competitive disadvantage for domestic
industries (Teslik, 2007). According to Bhagwati (2007), international companies or
industries may promote labor and environmental standards in order to gain a competitive
edge over more efficient producers from other countries in the global market. This is
because such standards would increase the production costs of their international rivals.
According to Schmidt (2009), individuals who support a trade agreement, that is met with
disapproval due to its perceived negative impact on the environment or human rights, may
suggest the incorporation of minimal labor and environmental regulations as a means of
appeasing those who oppose the agreement.
101
4.4. Conclusion
Government intervention has exerted a notable influence on the terms of trade
around the world, with varying degrees of involvement and impact. The North American
Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) is a notable example of governmental interference in
trade in North America. The inclusion of intellectual property protections in NAFTA was
advocated by the US government with the aim of safeguarding the interests of US
industries. Likewise, within the framework of the United States-Mexico-Canada
Agreement (USMCA), the government of the United States advocated for heightened entry
into the Canadian dairy market under government procurement provisions. The
aforementioned interventions are indicative of the political and economic interests that
underlie the actions of the respective governments, thereby highlighting the fact that “free
trade” agreements are not entirely devoid of government influence
49
. This in turn, what this
thesis attempts to justify, calls to take into consideration the labor and environmental
regulations for sustainable global development.
For decades, academics and policy makers have debated whether labor and
environmental norms should be included as criteria in trade agreements. Concerns about
the social and environmental consequences of trade liberalization and globalization
inspired a late-twentieth-century push to incorporate labor and environmental criteria in
trade treaties. However, implementation of these extended provisions seems to be a mere
49
According to Lal (2000), certain neoclassical theorists contend that state intervention should not be
employed to address market failures due to the potential for bureaucratic inefficiencies to exacerbate the
situation. Hence, free trade free market phenomenon should be completely devoid of government
intervention.
102
formality, and therefore fair trade movement arose in reaction to concerns about these
particular effects of trade liberalization and globalization.
Two auxiliary agreements were established concurrently with the founding of the
North American Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) in 1994. The North American
Agreement on Labor Cooperation (NAALC) and the North American Agreement on
Environmental Cooperation (NAAEC) are the names of these two accords. These two
accords were both signed in North America. These new agreements were a formal attempt
by the United States, Canada, and Mexico to include social and environmental
considerations into existing trade agreements. All three nations agreed to sign them. Since
then, labor and environmental requirements have been integrated into trade agreements at
all levels, including regional, bilateral, and global. Some supporters of adding labor and
environmental restrictions in trade agreements say that doing so would guarantee that trade
gains are distributed more equally and that social and environmental safeguards are
maintained. Skeptics, on the other hand, argue that there is a risk of negative effects for
competitiveness, costs, and sovereignty. It is noteworthy to mention Johnson, Sachs and
Sachs’s argument analyzing provisions regarding ISDS and environment (2016):
“Over the past year, we have been warning, for example, of
the threat the dead poses to sustainable development and the
environment. Unfortunately, recent developments have
done nothing to dispel these fears. Indeed, there is
growing evidence that a mechanism in the deal
represents a major grant of power to corporations, one
greatly disproportionate to the rights of all other
domestic actors including local governments, tribal
governments, environmental organizations, citizens,
and companies.
That mechanism, investor-state dispute settlement
(ISDS), gives multinational companies outlandish sway
over regulatory policies, including environmental
103
protection. The Obama administration told us not to
fear, but the use of ISDS in an existing deal, NAFTA,
underscores the seriousness of the threat as one of the
President’s most important environmental decisions is
now at risk. (para. 2-3)
Given the evidence of intervention by the governments to protect big corporations,
this thesis strongly defends the inclusion of labor and environmental protection laws as an
integral part of, first, the development policies and then, the international trade agreements.
This chapter particularly concludes that the integration of labor rights and environmental
standards should constitute a fundamental component of any novel trade accords that any
country in global north engages in, serving as an initial measure towards accomplishing
this objective. The enforcement of these codes may be achieved through the imposition of
trade penalties, similar to the enforcement of investor rights and intellectual property rights
as stipulated by the North American Free Trade Agreement and the World Trade
Organization. Additional examination of the methodology employed to implement these
provisions falls outside the purview of this thesis yet remains highly significant to
scrutinize. The production process necessitates crucial inputs, including labor and the
environment, which are both indispensable and scarce resources. It is imperative that in
forthcoming trade agreements, the treatment and consideration afforded to investors should
be extended to encompass the aforementioned group.
104
Chapter 5: Conclusion
The negative consequences of trade, such as job displacement and declining wages,
as well as environmental damage, grew dramatically in the 1990s, as new trade agreements
and massive increases in international capital flows drove rapid increases in trade volumes.
Despite these issues, global financial institutions are doing little to assist workers and
communities affected by globalization (Scott, 1998). In order to offer a case for fair trade,
this thesis aims to examine the ramifications of globalization, free trade, and a relatively
biased government action. Because the purpose of fair trade is to achieve greater fairness
and transparency in economic operations and trade on a global scale. It is important to note
that the certification-based fair trade model functions within the context of the free market,
thus this is another basic argument for promoting a more progressive
and radical approach on fair trade.
Two distinct conceptual frameworks were examined, both of which are
complimentary to the basics of a fair trading system. Sen's capabilities was first employed
as a conceptual framework. The capabilities equality approach focuses primarily on the
advancement of human capacities. This may be accomplished through developing and
executing fair trade policies that encourage worker capacities, particularly those of
marginalized and disadvantaged groups, expanded access to markets and jobs, and
technological innovation. It can also be used to improve distributional equity. Fair trade
policies, which guarantee that the advantages of trade are dispersed evenly across different
105
groups, will assist achieve this aim. Furthermore, the capabilities framework approach
encourages participatory decision making. By incorporating safety requirements into
manufacturing, fair trade rules can impact the decision-making power of employees and
customers. Finally, the capabilities approach promotes environmental stability, which
helps to prevent environmental degradation, natural resource depletion, and pollution, all
of which contribute to climate change and undermine the capabilities of vulnerable
communities, particularly those in developing countries. As a result, fair trade policies will
lead to environmental protection.
Second, the significance of Marx's criticisms of capitalism and his understanding
of exploitation to fair trade was studied. Marx maintained that workers are exploited under
capitalism by capitalists who take surplus value from their labor while paying them less
than the full worth of their job. This exploitation can result in inequality, poverty, and a
lack of fundamental necessities and opportunities. Marx's work is crucial in understanding
how multinational firms exploit employees in developing nations by extracting surplus
value from their labor in the framework of international commerce. Low earnings, terrible
working conditions, and restricted prospects for promotion can all contribute to this. It
especially influences conversations about the need to solve global economic exploitation
and injustice. Proposals for fair trade regimes use Marx's insights to create laws that
promote more justice and eliminate exploitation in global supply networks. Fair trade
policies, for example, can contain measures for worker empowerment, collective
bargaining, and livable wages, all with the goal of minimizing worker exploitation in
developing nations.
106
This thesis then went on to investigate and comprehend the flaws of free trade
policies. Many mainstream economists continue to believe that free trade is the only
strategy that will lead to the growth and development of nations and economies, which is
due to their unwarranted romanticization of the reductionist approach of classical and
neoclassical trade theories. These theories considerably simplify complex real-world
phenomena to basic variables. These theories were found to focus solely on factor
endowments, technological inequalities, and trade profits, while disregarding cultural,
political, and social factors that impact international commerce. A careful review of
literature on the limits of traditional trade models was used to do additional analysis.
Despite the fact that the new trade models incorporated more complex dynamics than
classic trade theories, such as strategic behavior, multiple equilibria, and endogenous
growth, they failed to explain the role of government in the context of sustainable
development.
The standard viewpoint characterizes the mainstream trade perspective, which is
still generally recognized and accepted. Neoclassical supporters continually push for free
international commerce. Historically, the notion of free trade was widely considered to be
the absence of state restrictions on the worldwide interchange of goods and services. Import
taxes, export and import quotas, licenses, and other measures geared especially at
managing trade flows are among the policy tools described above. The use of these policies
is seen to change naturally occurring trade patterns and reduce social well-being. Currently,
the concept of free trade includes the absence of technical trade barriers. Despite their
stated domestic objectives, the aforementioned laws are perceived to be excessively trade-
distorting (Bhagwati 1993).
107
In summary, it is suggested that differences in policy regimes across nations may
limit the reciprocal gains normally associated with free trade (Dorman, 1988). Disparities
in environmental and labor rules have the ability to disrupt trade and financial operations
that would otherwise take place, since they provide a competitive advantage to many
businesses in countries with lower social standards. According to this line of reasoning,
several supporters of labor and human rights, as well as environmental quality, argue that
their political initiatives are jeopardized by the consequences of free trade. Despite
evidence indicating negative effects of hyper-globalization resulting from unrestricted
trade, a significant number of economists maintain the belief that free trade is the only
strategy capable of promoting the growth and development of nations and economies. This
perspective is often influenced by an ideological inclination towards reductionist
approaches inherent in free trade theories. Interestingly, following a thorough examination
of evidence of government intervention in FTAs, this thesis concludes that "free trade" is
not truly free. There exists ample evidence of government interventions solely encouraging
and protecting large corporations and investors rather than the actual development and
sustainability factors, namely labor and the environment. All of this adds up to a persuasive
case for establishment of a fair trade regime that can strike a balance between a nation's
policy autonomy and its global commitments to raise labor and environmental standards.
To reiterate, fair trade certification within a free market system supports equitable
pricing for farmers and workers in developing countries. It functions within the present
market system, which is built on a capitalist paradigm that emphasizes profits above social
and environmental concerns. The willingness of consumers to pay extra for fair trade items
in order to support fair trade is dependent on market volatility and consumer demand. Fair
108
trade sales are rarely a consistent source of revenue for fair trade producers; therefore, they
may experience challenges depending on these fluctuations. Not only that, but wage
contraction over the last several decades has made it difficult for consumers to pay the fair
trade premium, forcing them to rely on cheaper replacements for fair trade products. As a
result, there is a need to create a more progressive fair trade framework in which states may
exercise policy autonomy while adhering to their international labor and environmental
responsibilities.
Following a thorough examination of evidence of government intervention in
FTAs, this thesis concludes that "free trade" has never been free and that it must be replaced
by a global fair trade regime in which nations can exercise their autonomy. There is an
urgent need to alter the role of government in sustaining social and environmental
conditions for national development and progress. The evidence of clauses safeguarding
large firms and investors highlights the significance of worker rights and environmental
standards as essential agenda items for any future international trade agreements. These
codes may be enforced by trade sanctions, tariffs, and charters, in the same way as investor
and intellectual property rights are enforced under the NAFTA and WTO accords. Labor
and the environment are vital, rare resources and key inputs to the production and
development processes, and they should be accorded the same amount of attention and
reverence in all trade agreements as investors and multinational firms. Incorporating labor
and environmental standards into trade agreements is an important step toward promoting
equitable trade benefits for all stakeholders, rather than just dominant corporations and
developed countries. To be effective, these standards must be provided with greater gravity
and enforcement methods than simple provisions.
109
References
Abbott, R. B., Bader, R., Bajjali L., ElSamen T. A., Obeidat T., Sboul, H.,
Shwayat, M. & Alabbadi, I. (2012). The price of medicines in Jordan: The cost of trade-
based intellectual property. Journal of Generic Medicines.
Acemoglu, D., & Akcigit, U. (2012). Intellectual property rights policy,
competition and innovation. Journal of the European Economic Association, 10(1), 1-42.
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., & Robinson, J. A. (2012). The colonial origins of
comparative development: An empirical investigation. American Economic
Review, 102(6), 3077-3110.
Ahmad, E., Drèze, J., Hills, J., & Sen, A. (Eds.). (1991). Social security in
developing countries. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
Alawi, R. & Alabbadi, I. (2015). Investigating the effect of data exclusivity on the
pharmaceutical sector in Jordan. Jordan Journal of Pharmaceutical Sciences.
Amadeo, K. (2021). CAFTA Explained, With its Pros and Cons. The Balance
Amsden, A. H. (2008). The wild ones: industrial policies in the developing
world. The Washington consensus reconsidered: Towards a new global governance, 95-
118.
110
Andrew, R. M., Peters, G. P. (2021). The Global Carbon Project's fossil CO2
emissions dataset. Zenodo.
Appleyard, D. R., Field, A. J., and Steven L. Cobb. 2006. International Economics.
Boston: McGraw-Hill/Irwin.
Aspromourgos, T. (2009). The Science of Wealth: Adam Smith and the Framing
of Political Economy, London: Routledge.
Baccaro, L. (2001). Civil society, NGOs, and decent work policies: Sorting out the
issues.
Bairoch, Paul. 1995. Economics and World History: Myths and Paradoxes.
University of Chicago Press.
Baldwin, R. E. (1989). The new protectionism: A response to shift in economic
power? Cambridge Journal of Economics, 13(2), 203-220.
Baldwin, Robert E. (1987). Multilateral Liberalization.
Baldwin, Robert E. (1995). An Economic Evaluation of the Uruguay Round
Agreements. World Economy-London, 18: 153-153.
Baver, S. (2011). NAFTA, CAFTA and the Environment: The Role of Institutions.
IdeAs (Vanves, France).
111
Berger-Tal, O., Nathan, J., Meron, E., & Saltz, D. (2014). The exploration-
exploitation dilemma: a multidisciplinary framework. PloS one, 9(4), e95693.
Bhagwati, J. (1991). Jumpstarting Gatt. Foreign Policy, (83), 105-118.
Bhagwati, J. (1993). The case for free trade. Scientific American, 269(5), 42-49.
Bhagwati, J. (2004). In Defense of Globalization: With a New Afterword. Oxford
University Press.
Bhagwati, J. N. (1990a). Departures from Multilateralism: Regionalism and
Aggressive Unilateralism.
Bhagwati, J. N. (1995). Trade liberalization and" fair trade" demands addressing
the environmental and labor standards issues.
Bhagwati, J. N. (2007). Interview by Lee Hudson Teslik: U.S. Must Rethink Doha
Demands
Bhagwati, J. N., & Hudec, R. E. (Eds.). (1996). Fair trade and harmonization:
Prerequisites for free trade? MIT Press, (Vol. 1).
Bhagwati, J. N., & Srinivasan, T. N. (1982). The welfare consequences of directly-
unproductive profit-seeking (DUP) lobbying activities: Price versus quantity
distortions. Journal of International Economics, 13(1-2), 33-44.
112
Bhagwati, J., Krishna, P., & Panagariya, A. (2014). The world trade system: trends
and challenges. Unpublished paper, Department of Economics, Columbia University.
Brown, G. E., Goold, J. W., and Cavanagh, J. (1992). Making Trade Fair. World
Policy Journal, 9(2), 309-327.
Bull, R. T. (2022). Improving International Regulatory Cooperation in an Age of
Trade Skepticism. Brookings.
Burgoon, B., & Hiscox, M. (2000). Trade openness and political compensation:
labor demands for adjustment assistance. In Annual Meeting of the American Political
Science Association.
Burkett, P. (2006). Marxism and ecological economics: Toward a red and green
political economy. Brill.
Caine, P. (2020). Environmental impact of COVID-19 lockdowns seen from
space. Chicago News.
Castañeda, J. G., & Heredia, C. (1992). Another NAFTA: what a good agreement
should offer. World Policy Journal, 9(4), 673-685.
Castro, A. (2015). Intellectual Property Rights in CAFTA-DR and
Pharmaceuticals in Costa Rica. Costa Rica Five Years after CAFTA-DR, 89.
113
Chang, H. J. (2001). Intellectual Property Rights and Economic Development:
Historical Lessons and Emerging Issues. Journal of Human Development 2, no. 2: 287-
309.
Chang, H. J. (2002). Kicking Away the Ladder: An Unofficial History of
Capitalism, especially in Britain and the United States. Challenge, 45(5), 63–97.
Chang, H. J. (2003). Rethinking Development Economics. Anthem Press
Chang, H. J. (2007). Bad samaritans: Rich nations, poor policies, and the threat to
the developing world (p. 16). New York: Random House Business.
Chang, H. J., & Green, D. (2003). The Northern WTO Agenda on Investment: Do
as we say, not as we did. Geneva: South Centre.
Chang, H. J., Grabel, I. (2014). Reclaiming Development: An Alternative
Economic Policy Manual. Zed Books Ltd.
Chapman, D. (1991). Environmental Standards and International Trade in Auto-
mobiles and Copper: The Case for a Social Tariff. Natural Resources Journal 31, no. 3,
449-61.
Chene, M. (2017). Anti-Corruption and Transparency Provisions in Trade
Agreements. Transparency International. Germany.
Clark, D. A. (2005). The Capability Approach: Its Development, Critiques and
Recent Advances.
114
Coleman, D. C. (1957). Eli Heckscher and the idea of mercantilism. Scandinavian
Economic History Review, 5(1), 3-25.
Connor, T., and Dent, K. (2006). Offside! Labor Rights and Sportswear Production
in Asia.
Cooney, S. (1998). Testing times for the ILO: institutional reform for the new
international political economy. Comp. Lab. L. & Pol'y J., 20, 365.
Cooper, R. N. (1994). Environment and Resource Policies for the Integrated World
Economy. Brookings Institution Press.
Coppolaro, L. (2018). In the Shadow of Globalization: The European Community
and the United States in the GATT Negotiations of the Tokyo Round (1973–1979). The
International History Review, 40(4), 752-773.
Correa, C. M. (2007). Trade Related Aspects of Intellectual Property Rights - A
Commentary on the TRIPS Agreement 6, Oxford U. Press
Crocker, D. A. (1992). Functioning and Capability: The Foundations of Sen’s and
Nussbaum’s Development Ethic, Political Theory 20 (4):584–612.
Crowley, M. A. (2003). An introduction to the WTO and GATT. Economic
Perspectives, 4(2003), 42-57.
Davidson, C., Martin, L., & Wilson, J. D. (2007). Efficient black markets? Journal
of Public Economics, 91(7-8), 1575-1590.
115
Davis, G. F. (2003). Philosophical psychology and economic psychology in David
Hume and Adam Smith. History of Political Economy, 35(2), 269-304.
Davis, S. J., & Caldeira, K. (2010). Consumption-based accounting of CO2
emissions. Proceedings of the national academy of sciences, 107(12), 5687-5692.
Deardorff, A. V. (1982). The general validity of the Heckscher-Ohlin theorem.
American Economic Review 72 (4): 683–94.
Deardorff, A. V. (1984). Comparative advantage and international trade and
investment in services.
Deardorff, A. V. (1984). Testing trade theories and predicting trade
flows. Handbook of international economics, 1, 467-517.
Deardorff, A. V. (2005). Innovation and growth in the global economy. MIT Press
Books.
DeMartino, G. (2000). Global Economy, Global Justice: Theoretical and Policy
Alternatives to Neoliberalism. Routledge.
DeMartino, G. (2002). Global Economy, Global Justice: Theoretical and Policy
Alternatives to Neoliberalism. Taylor and Francis
DeMartino, G. (2019). Free trade or social tariffs? In The Handbook of
Globalisation, Third Edition. Edward Elgar Publishing
116
DeMartino, G. F., Moyer, J. D., & Watkins, K. M. (2014). Achieving fair trade
through a social tariff regime: a policy thought experiment. Cambridge Journal of
Economics, 40(1), 69-92.
Dorman, P. (1988). Worker rights and international trade: a case for
intervention. Review of Radical Political Economics, 20(2-3), 241-246.
Dorman, Peter. (1992). The Social Tariff Approach to International Disparities in
Environmental and Workers' Rights Standards: History, Theory, and Some Initial Evidence.
Drezner, D. W. (2001). Globalization and policy convergence. International
Studies Review, 3(1), 53-78.
Dur, A., Baccini, L., & Elsig, M. (2014). The design of international trade
agreements: introducing a new ¨ dataset. The Review of International Organizations, 9(3),
353–375.
Eagleton, T. (2015). The Politics of Barbarism. In Barbarism Revisited. Brill, pp.
377-383.
Eagleton, T., & Mosquera, AS (2011). Why Marx was right. Barcelona:
Peninsula.
Edelman, M., & Haugerud, A. (2005). The anthropology of development and
globalization: From classical political economy to contemporary neoliberalism.
Eisenberg, J. (2005). Free trade vs. fair trade. Global Envision.
117
Elliott, K. A., & Freeman, R. B. (2003). Can labor standards improve under
globalization? Peterson Institute Press: All Books.
Elsig, Hoekman, B., & Pauwelyn, J. (2017). Assessing the World Trade
Organization: Fit for Purpose? Cambridge University Press.
Elson, D., & Pearson, R. (1981). ‘Nimble fingers make cheap workers’: An
analysis of women's employment in third world export manufacturing. Feminist
Review, 7(1), 87-107.
Emerson, J. W. et al. (2012). Environmental Performance Index and Pilot Trend
Environmental Performance Index. New Have: Yale Center for Environmental Law and
Policy
Esty, Daniel C. (2001). Bridging the Trade-Environment Divide. Journal of
Economic Perspectives 15, no. 3: 113-130.
Evans, J. W. (1971). The Kennedy round in American trade policy: the twilight of
the GATT? Harvard University Press.
Feenstra, R. C. (2018). Alternative sources of the gains from international trade:
Variety, creative destruction, and markups. Journal of Economic Perspectives, 32(2), 25-
46.
Fletcher, Ian. 2010. Free Trade Doesn’t Work: What Should Replace it and Why?
Washington, DC: US Business and Industry Council.
118
Foster, J. B. (2015). The Great Capitalist Climacteric: Marxism and System
Change Not Climate Change. Monthly Review, 67(6), 1.
Foster, J. B., & Holleman, H. (2014). The theory of unequal ecological exchange:
a Marx-Odum dialectic. Journal of Peasant Studies, 41(2), 199-233.
Fridell, G. (2006). Fair trade and Neoliberalism: Assessing Emerging
Perspectives. Latin American Perspective, 33(6), 8-28
Fridell, G. (2007). Fair-Trade coffee and commodity fetishism: The limits of
market-driven social justice. Historical Materialism, 15(4), 79-104.
Fridell, G., Gross, Z., & McHugh, S. (2021). The Fair Trade Handbook: Building
a Better World, Together. Fernwood Publishing Print.
Friedlingstein, P., et al. (2022). Global carbon budget 2021. Earth System Science
Data, 14(4), 1917-2005.
Friedman, Sheldon. (1992). NAFTA as Social Dumping. Challenge 35, no. 5, pp.27-
32.
Galindo Martin, & Nissan, E. (2010). International political economy. Nova
Science Publishers.
Gamble, A. (1994). Britain in decline: economic policy, political strategy, and the
British state. Bloomsbury Publishing.
119
Gandolfo, G. (1994). International economics I. Berlin: Springer
Gasper, D. (2013). Climate change and the language of human security. Ethics,
Policy & Environment, 16(1), 56-78.
Geysmans, R., & Hustinx, L. (2016). Placing the distant other on the shelf: An
analysis and comparison of (fair trade) coffee packages in relation to commodity
fetishism. Sociological Research Online, 21(1), 35-40.
Ghosh, S. (2015). Environmental standards and political federalism: Do labor
legislations matter? Environmental development, 16, 15-30.
Gilbert, R. (1986). Winham. International Trade and the Tokyo Round
Negotiations, 314.
Gitterman, D. P. (2003). European integration and labour market cooperation: a
comparative regional perspective. Journal of European Social Policy, 13(2), 99-120.
Global Carbon Project. (2021). Supplemental data of Global Carbon Project 2021
(1.0) [Data set]. Global Carbon Project.
Greenhouse, S., & Barbaro, M. (2006). An ugly side of free trade: Sweatshops in
Jordan. New York Times, 3.
Grossman, G. M., & Helpman, E. (1995). Trade wars and trade talks. Journal of
political Economy, 103(4), 675-708.
120
Grossman, G. M., & Krueger, A. B. (1991). Environmental impacts of a North
American free trade agreement.
Grossman, G. M., & Krueger, A. B. (1995). Economic growth and the
environment. The quarterly journal of economics, 110(2), 353-377.
Gubbay, M. B., Conconi, P., Parenti, M. (2021). Lobbying for Globalization: How
the Winners Dominate the Politics of Trade Agreements.
Hahm, H., König, T., Osnabrügge, M., & Frech, E. (2019). Who settles disputes?
treaty design and trade attitudes toward the transatlantic trade and investment partnership
(TTIP). International Organization, 73(4), 881-900
Hakobyan, S., & McLaren, J. (2016). Looking for local labor market effects of
NAFTA. Review of Economics and Statistics, 98(4), 728-741.
Hampton, P. (2008) Fair trade, free trade and socialism.
Hampton, P. (2015). Workers and trade unions for climate solidarity: Tackling
climate change in a neoliberal world. Routledge.
Hang, X., Goel, R. K., Jiang, J., & Capasso, S. (2023). Do deep regional trade
agreements strengthen anti-corruption? A social network analysis. The World
Economy, 00, 1– 24.
Hanley, R., Paganelli, M. P. (2014). Adam Smith on Money, Mercantilism, and
the System of Natural Liberty. Oxford University Studies in the Enlightenment.
121
Harris JM Roach B. (2018). Environmental and Natural Resource Economics: A
Contemporary Approach. 4th ed. Florence: Taylor and Francis.
Heckscher, E. F. (1919). The effect of foreign trade on income distribution. Some
theoretical basics. Economic Journal, 1-32.
Heckscher, E. F. (1950). Multilateralism, Baltic trade, and the mercantilists. The
Economic History Review, 3(2), 219-228.
Heckscher, E. F. 1(991). The effect of foreign trade on the distribution of income.
Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Helpman, E. (1981). International trade in the presence of product differentiation,
economies of scale and monopolistic competition: A Chamberlin-Heckscher-Ohlin
approach. Journal of international economics, 11(3), 305-340.
Helpman, E., & Krugman, P. R. (1985). Market structure and foreign trade:
Increasing returns, imperfect competition, and the international economy. MIT Press
Books.
Hirsh, P. (2019), Economists on the run, Foreign Policy, available at:
https://foreignpolicy. com/2019/10/22/economists-globalization-trade-paul-krugman-
china/ (accessed 20 July 2020).
122
Holland, S. (2015). After Ricardo–after Marx–after Keynes: Comparative
Advantage, Mutual Advantage and Implications for Global Governance. Review of
Keynesian Economics, 3(1), 29-44.
Hudson, I., & Hudson, M. (2003). Removing the veil? Commodity fetishism, fair
trade, and the environment. Organization & environment, 16(4), 413-430.
Hufbauer, G. C., Schott, J. J., Dunnigan, R., & Clark, D. (1993). NAFTA: An
assessment. Peterson Institute.
Hume, David. (1752). Political discourses. Edinburgh: Printed by R. Fleming
IPCC, Climate Change. (2013). The Physical Science Basis. Contribution of
Working Group I to the Fifth Assessment Report of IPCC on Climate Change. Cambridge
University Press, Cambridge, UK.
Irwin, D. A. (1996). Against the Tide: An Intellectual History of Free Trade.
Princeton University Press.
Irwin, D. A. (2015). Free Trade Under Fire. Princeton University Press.
Irwin, D., Mavroidis, P., & Sykes, A. (2008). The Negotiation of the GATT.
In The Genesis of the GATT. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Irwin, Douglas A. 2015. Free Trade Under Fire. Princeton University Press.
Johnson, H. G. (1971). Aspects of the Theory of Tariffs. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press.
123
Johnson, L., Sachs, L., Sachs, J. (2016). The real danger in TPP. CNN
Kabeer, N. (2004). Globalization, labor standards, and women's rights: dilemmas
of collective (in) action in an interdependent world. Feminist Economics, 10(1), 3-35.
Kabeer, N. (2008). Mainstreaming gender in social protection for the informal
economy. Commonwealth Secretariat.
Kabeer, N. (2008). Paid work, women's empowerment and gender justice: Critical
pathways of social change.
Kennedy, M. (2015). Blurred Lines: Reading TRIPS with GATT Glasses. Journal
of World Trade, 49(5), 735–755.
Kim, S.Y. (2015). Deep integration and regional trade agreements. In Martin, L.
(Ed.), The Oxford handbook of the political economy of international trade (pp. 360–384).
Oxford University Press.
Kim, S.Y., Mansfield, E.D., & Milner, H.V. (2016). Regional trade governance.
In Borzel, T.A., & Risse, T. (Eds.), The Oxford handbook of comparative regionalism (pp.
323–360). Oxford University Press.
Kim, Y. M., & Park, K. S. (2014). Labor Share and Economic Growth.
Koehler-Geib, F., & Sanchez, S. M. (Eds.). (2015). Costa Rica five years after
cafta-dr: Assessing early results. World Bank Publications.
124
Kravis, I. B. (1956). Wages and foreign trade. The review of Economics and
Statistics, 14-30.
Kravis, Irving B., Alan Heston and Robert Summers. (1982). World Product and
Income: International Comparisons of Real Gross Product. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins
University Press.
Kraw, G. (1990). The Community Charter of the Fundamental Social Rights of
Workers. Hastings International and Comparative Law Review 13, 471-77.
Krueger, A. O. (1978). Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development. Vol.
X: Liberalization Attempts and Consequences. Foreign Affairs 58, no. 2 (1978): 421.
doi:10.2307/20040442.
Krueger, A. O. (1984). Comparative Advantage and Development Policy 20 years
Later. In Economic Structure and Performance, pp. 135-156. Academic Press.Krueger, A.
O. (1990). Asian Trade and Growth Lessons. The American Economic Review 80, no. 2.
Krueger, A. O. (1990). Asian Trade and Growth Lessons. The American Economic
Review 80, no. 2.
Krueger, A. O. (2010). India’s trade with the world: Retrospect and
prospect. India’s economy: Performance and challenges, 399-429.
Krugman, P. (1997). In praise of cheap labor. Slate.
Krugman, P. (2007). Divided over trade. The New York Times
125
Krugman, P. R. (1979). Increasing returns, monopolistic competition, and
international trade. Journal of International Economics, 9(4), 469-479.
Krugman, P. R. (1981). Trade, Accumulation and Uneven Development. Journal
of Development Economics 8, no. 2: 149-161.
Krugman, P. R. (1985). Increasing Returns Imperfect Competition and International
Trade. Cambridge, MA: M.I.T. Press.
Krugman, P. R. (1987). Is Free Trade Passé? Journal of Economic Perspectives 1,
no. 2: 31-144.
Krugman. (1990). Rethinking international trade. MIT Press.
Krugman. (2011). The Profession and the Crisis. Eastern Economic Journal,
37(3), 307–312.
Kyle, M. K. & McGahan, A.M. (2012). Investments in pharmaceuticals before and
after TRIPS. The Review of Economics and Statistics.
La Barca, G. (2020). The US, the EC and World Trade: From the Kennedy Round
to the Start of the Uruguay Round. Bloomsbury Publishing.
La Barca. (2016). The US, the EC and World Trade: From the Kennedy Round to
the Start of the Uruguay Round. Bloomsbury Publishing.
LaHaye, L. (2008). Mercantilism In: The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics.
Palgrave Macmillan, London.
126
Lal, Deepak. (2000). The Poverty of "Development Economics". No. 16. MIT
Press.
Lall, S., & Streeten, P. (1977). Foreign investment, transnationals and developing
countries. Springer.
Laws, F. (2005). Senate weighs DR-CAFTA pros, cons. Southwest Farm Press.
Lazare. (2006). Human trafficking in Jordan. Multinational Monitor, 27(3), 7–.
Lea, B. D. (2018). NAFTA 2.0: What to Know. FOX Business.
Leamer, E. E. (1980). The Leontief paradox, reconsidered. Journal of political
Economy, 88(3), 495-503.
Lebowitz, M. (1988). Trade and Class: Labor Strategies in a World of Strong Capital.
Studies in Political Economy 27, 137-48.
Linder, P. H., & Williamson, J. G. (2016). Unequal gains: American Growth and
Inequality Since 1700. Princeton University Press.
Locke, R. M., and Romis, N. (2007). Improving Work Conditions in a Global
Supply Chain. MIT Sloan
Long, H. (2020). The USMCA is Finally Done. Here’s What is in it. Washington
Post.
127
Lustig, N. C., Bosworth, B. P., & Lawrence, R. Z. (Eds.). (2010). North American
free trade: Assessing the impact. Brookings Institution Press.
Lyon, S. (2010). Coffee and community: Maya farmers and fair-trade markets.
University Press of Colorado.
Magnusson, E. A., Wayne, O. (2017). The Death of TPP: The Best Thing That
Ever Happened to China. The National Interest
Magnusson, L. (1978). Eli Heckscher, mercantilism, and the favorable balance of
trade. Scandinavian Economic History Review, 26:2, 103-127.
Mamic, I. (2004). Implementing codes of conduct: How businesses manage social
performance in global supply chains. International Labor Organization.
Manger, M.S., & Shadlen, K.C. (2014). Political trade dependence and north–
south trade agreements. International Studies Quarterly, 58(1), 79–91.
Maret, E., & Finlay, B. (1984). The distribution of household labor among women
in dual-earner families. Journal of Marriage and the Family, 357-364.
Markusen, J. R. (1986). Explaining the Volume of Trade: An Eclectic Approach.
American Economic Review 76, 1002-1011.
Marshall, A. (1890). Principles of Economics. Macmillan and Co.
128
Martinez-Alier, J. (2002). Ecological debt and property rights on carbon sinks and
reservoirs. Capitalism Nature Socialism, 13(1), 115-119.
Marx, K. (1848). On the Question of Free Trade. Public Speech Delivered by Karl
Marx before the Democratic Association of Brussels. Retrieved from:
https://www.panarchy.org/engels/freetrade.html
Marx, K. (1887). Capital: A Criticism on Political Economy. Today: Monthly
Magazine of Scientific Socialism, (45), 57-61.
Marx, K. (1961). Economic and philosophical manuscripts (p. 107). Lawrence &
Wishart.
Marx, K. (1976). 1867. Capital: A Critique of Political Economy. New York:
International.
Marx, K. (1992). Capital: volume III (Vol. 3). Penguin UK.
Marx, K. (2004). Capital: volume I (Vol. 1). Penguin UK.
Marx, K., & Engels, F. (1850). Address of the central committee to the communist
league (pp. 505-11). Communist League.
Marx, K., & Engels, F. (1973). On colonialism: articles from the New York
Tribune and other writings.
Marx, Karl. (1973). Grundrisse. New York: Vintage.
129
Mazzucato, M. (2018). The Value of Everything: Making and Taking in the Global
Economy. Hachette UK.
McCauley, D., & Heffron, R. (2018). Just transition: Integrating climate, energy
and environmental justice. Energy Policy, 119, 1-7.
McGonnigal, C. (2012). Karl Marx and the Fair Trade Chocolate Industry in the
Ivory Coast. Clocks and Clouds, 2(1).
Meek, R.L and Skinner, A.S. (1973). The Development of Adam Smith’s ideas on
the Division of Labor, Economic Journal
Mill, J. S. (1848). Principles of Political Economy. John W. Parker.
Muradian, R., O'Connor, M., & Martinez-Alier, J. (2002). Embodied pollution in
trade: estimating the ‘environmental load displacement of industrialized
countries. Ecological Economics, 41(1), 51-67.
National Bureau of Statistics of China. (2018). China Statistical Yearbook
Nilsen, P. (2020). Making sense of implementation theories, models, and
frameworks. Implementation Science 3.0, 53-79.
Norman, J. (2018). The USMCA: What Does it Mean for Patents and The
Pharmaceutical Industry? Gowling WLG
130
Nussbaum, M. and Sen, A.K. (1989). The Quality of Life, Oxford: Clarendon
Press
Nussbaum, M. C. (2000). Women and human development: The capabilities
approach (Vol. 3). Cambridge university press.
O’Brien, P. K., & Williams, G. (2016). Global Political Economy: Evolution and
Dynamics. Palgrave Macmillan.
Ohlin, B. (1933). Interregional and International Trade. Cambridge: Harvard
University Press.
Osgood, I., Feng., (2017). Intellectual property provisions and support for US trade
agreements. CrossMark
Palley, T. I. (2006). Rethinking trade and trade policy: Gomory, Baumol, and
Samuelson on comparative advantage (No. 86). Public Policy Brief.
Parry, J. H. (1967). Transport and Trade Routes. Cambridge Economic History of
Europe.
Pearson, T. W. (2013). Life Is Not for Sale!: Confronting Free Trade and
Intellectual Property in Costa Rica. American Anthropologist, 115(1), 58–71.
Prasch, Robert E. (1996). Reassessing the Theory of Comparative Advantage.
Review of Political Economy 8, no. 1: 37-56. Ravenhill, J. (2014). Global Value Chains
and Development. Review of International Political Economy, 21(1): 270.
131
Raynolds, L. T., & Bennett, E. A. (2015). Introduction to research on fair trade.
In Handbook of research on fair trade (pp. 3-23). Edward Elgar Publishing.
Ribeiro, H. (2015). Free-trade Agreements: Challenges for Global Health.
Ricardo, D. (1817). Principles of Political Economy and Taxation. G. Bell.
Ricardo, D. (1817). The principles of political economy and taxation of David
Ricardo. Macmillan.
Ricardo, David. (1817) The principles of political economy and taxation of David
Ricardo. Macmillan
Richards, D. G. (2002). Globalizing intellectual property rights: the TRIPS
agreement. London: Routledge.
Richards, D.G. (2004). Intellectual property rights and global capitalism. ME
Sharpe
Riley, C. (2017). Trump's decision to kill TPP leaves door open for China. CNN
Money, 24.
Riley, C. (2017). Trump’s Decision to Kill TPP Leaves Door Open for China. CNN
Rodrik, D. (1995). Getting Interventions Right: how South Korea and Taiwan
Grew Rich. Economic policy 10, no. 20: 53-107.
132
Rodrik, D. (1997). Has Globalization Gone Too Far? Washington: Institute for
International Economics.
Rodrik, D. (2004). Getting Institutions Right. CESifo Economic Sudies, 50(1), 1-
29
Rodrik, D. (2017). Populism and the Economics of Globalization. NBER Working
Paper No. 23559.
Rodrik, D. (2018). What Do Trad Agreements Really Do? Journal of Economic
Perspectives. Vol 32. No. 2.
Romalis. (2007). NAFTA’s and CUSFTA’s Impact on International Trade. The
Review of Economics and Statistics, 89(3), 416–435.
Rothstein, R. (1993). Setting the Standard: International Labor Rights and U.S. Trade
Policy. Economic Policy Institute.
Runge, C. F. (1994). Free trade, protected environment balancing trade
liberalization and environmental interests. Council on Foreign Relations.
Sachs, J. (2015). TPP is too flawed for a simple 'yes' vote. The Boston Globe
Sachs, J. (2017). Why the TPP is Too Flawed for a ‘Yes’ Vote in Congress.
Sachs, J. D. (2015). Investing in social capital. World happiness report, 152-166.
Samuelson, P. A. (1948). International trade and the equalization
133
Schmidt, A. R. (2009). A new trade policy for America: Do labor and
environmental provisions in trade agreements serve social interests or special interests. Ind.
Int'l & Comp. L. Rev., 19, 167.
Schmidt, O. (2005). Understanding the Case of International Labor Standards
Methodology Insights into an Ongoing Debate. MPRA Paper, University Library of
Munich.
Scott, R. E. (1998). Free Trade in the Americas: Labor and Environmental
Concern. Economic Policy Institute
Sen, A. (1980). Equality of what? In S. McMurrin (ed.), The Tanner Lectures on
Human Values. Salt Lake City: University of Utah Press.
Sen, A. (1985). Commodities and Capabilities. Amsterdam: North Holland.
Sen, A. (1987). The standard of living. In G. Hawthorn (ed.), The Standard of
Living. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Sen, A. (1992a). Inequality Re-examined. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Sen, A. (1992b). Missing women. British Medical Journal, 304, 586–87.
Sen, A. (1993). Capability and well-being. In Martha Nussbaum and Amartya Sen
(eds), The Quality of Life. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
Sen, A. (1999). Development as Freedom. New York: Knopf.
134
Sen, A. (2004). Capabilities, lists, and public reason: continuing the conversation.
Feminist Economics, 10, 77–80.
Sen, A., Williams, B. A. O., & Williams, B. (Eds.). (1982). Utilitarianism and
beyond. Cambridge University Press.
Sengupta, R. (2012). Government Procurement in the EU-India FTA: Dangers for
India. Economic and Political Weekly.
Shafaeddin, M. (1998). How did developed countries industrialize? The history of
Trade and Industrial Policy: The cases of Great Britain and the USA (No. 139). United
Nations Conference on Trade and Development.
Shaffer, E. R. & Brenner, J. E. (2009). A trade agreement’s impact on access to
generic drugs. Health Affairs.
Shaikh, A. (2003). Globalization and the Myth of Free Trade: 50-68.
Shrybman, Steven. (1992). Trading Away the Environment. World Policy Journal 9,
no. 1
Silvia, S. (1991). The Social Charter of the European Community: A Defeat for
European Labor. Industrial and Labor Relations Review 44, no. 4, 626-41.
Sindzingre, A. N. (2018). Can the concept of exploitation be associated with that
of interiorization? A critical analysis. Cahiers d’économie politique, (2), 203-226.
135
Smith, A. (1776). An inquiry into the nature and causes of the wealth of nations.
London: Clarendon.
Steedman, I. (1971). Trade amongst growing economies. Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press. Steedman, I. (Ed.). (1979). Fundamental issues in trade theory. London:
Macmillan.
Steedman, I. (1979). Fundamental Issues in Trade Theory. Springer
Steedman, I. (1995). The Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies,
LXIII, 111–112.
Steedman, I. and Metcalfe, J. S. (1973). On foreign trade. Economica
Internazionale, 26, 516–528.
Stiglitz JE 2019. People, power, and profits: Progressive capitalism for an age of
discontent. London
Stiglitz, J. (2002, September). Development policies in a world of globalization.
In New International Trends for Economic Development Seminar (pp. 1-27).
Stiglitz, J. (2015). Under TPP, Polluters Could Sue U.S. for Setting Carbon
Emissions Limits. Democracy Now.
Stiglitz, J. E. (1986). The New Development Economics. World Development Vol.
14, no. 2: 257-265.
136
Stiglitz, J. E. (1989). Markets, Market Failures and Development. The American
Economic Review 79, no. 2: 197-203.
Stiglitz, J. E. (2004). The Post Washington Consensus. The Initiative for Policy
Dialogue: 1-15.
Stiglitz, J. E. (2015). The Trans-Pacific Free-Trade Charade. Project Syndicate
Stolper, W. F., & Samuelson, P. A. (1941). Protection and real wages. Review of
Economic Studies, 9, 50–73.
Subasat, T. (2001) Review of Radical Political Economics. Spring, Volume 35,
No. 2, 148-165
Subasat, T. (2002). A political economy critique of the Ricardian comparative
advantage theory.
Subasat, T. (2002). Does export promotion increase economic growth? Some
cross‐section evidence. Development Policy Review, 20(3), 333-349.
Summers, C. (2001). The Battle in Seattle: Free Trade, Labor Rights, and Societal
Values.
Suri, V., & Chapman, D. (1998). Economic growth, trade and energy: implications
for the environmental Kuznets curve. Ecological economics, 25(2), 195-208.
137
Taylor, H. (1972). Trade, Neutrality and the 'English Road', 1630-1648,"
Economic History Review.
Trachtenberg et al., (2019). Trade Treaties and Access to Medicines: What Does
the Evidence Tell Us?
Trachtenberg, D., Kaplan, W.A., Wirtz, V.J. & Gallagher, K. (2018). The effects
of trade agreements on imports of biologics: evidence from Chile. GEGI Working Paper.
Van den Putte, L., De Ville, F., & Orbie, J. (2015). The European Parliament as
an international actor in trade: From power to impact. In The European Parliament and its
international relations (pp. 52-69). Routledge.
Vanek, J. (1968). The factor proportions theory: The n-factor case. Kyklos, 21(4),
749-756.
Viner, J. (2016). Studies in the theory of international trade. Routledge.
Wallerstein, I. (2011). The Modern World-System IV: Centrist Liberalism
Triumphant, 1789-1914. University of California Press.
Wallerstein, I. M. (1980). Mercantilism and the Consolidation of the European
World-Economy, 1600–1750, The Modern World-System.
Warren, E. (2015). The trans-pacific partnership clause everyone should oppose.
138
Weaver. (2011). The United States and the global economy: from Bretton Woods
to the current crisis (pp. xi–xi). The Rowman & Littlefield Publishing Group.
Webb, J. (2007). Seduced or Skeptical Consumers? Organized Action and the
Case of Fair Trade Coffee. Sociological Research Online, 12(3), 73-85.
Weingast, Barry R. (2018). War, Trade, and Mercantilism: Reconciling Adam
Smith's Three Theories of the British Empire.
Wiebe, K. S., Yamano, N. (2016). Estimating CO2 Emissions Embodied in Final
Demand and Trade Using the OECD ICIO 2015: Methodology and Results. OECD
Science, Technology, and Innovation.
Williams, E. (2021). Capitalism and slavery. UNC Press Books.
Winham, G. R. (1986). International Trade and the Tokyo Round negotiations.
Princeton.
Wolf, M. (1987). Why Trade Liberalization is a Good Idea.
Woodin, A. (2012). Fair Trade: An Analysis of The Relationship Among
Producers And Consumers. In Fourth Annual General Business Conference (p. 229).
Yamano, N., & Guilhoto, J. (2020). CO2 emissions embodied in international
trade and domestic final demand: Methodology and results using the OECD Inter-Country
Input-Output Database.
139
Yan, Y. (2022). The Inclusion of Anti-Corruption Clauses in International
Investment Agreements and its Possible Systemic Implications. Asian Journal of WTO &
International Health Law and Policy. Vol. 17, No. 1, pp. 141-173.
Yoshihara, N. (2017). A Progress Report on Marxian Economic Theory: On the
Controversies In Exploitation Theory Since Okishio. Journal of Economic Surveys, 31(2),
632-659. ea
Zeiler, T. W. (2012). The Expanding Mandate of the GATT: The First Seven
Rounds. In The Oxford Handbook on The World Trade Organization. Oxford University
Press.
Zheng et al., (2019). Drivers of change in China’s energy-related CO
2
emissions.
Proceedings of the National Academy of Science. Royal Swedish Academy of Sciences,
Stockholm, Sweden.
Zheng, J., Mi, Z., Coffman, D. M., Shan, Y., Guan, D., & Wang, S. (2019). The
slowdown in China’s carbon emissions growth in the new phase of economic
development. One Earth, 1(2), 240-253.