Employment Hysteresis
from the Great Recession
Danny Yagan
University of California, Berkeley, and National Bureau of Economic Research
This paper uses US local areas as a laboratory to test for long-term im-
pacts of the Great Recession. In administrative longitudinal data, I es-
timate that exposure to a 1 percentage point larger 20079 local un-
employment shock reduced 2015 working-age employment rates by
over 0.3 percentage points. Rescaled, this long-term recession impact
accounts for over half of the 200715 US age-adjusted employment de-
cline. Impacts were larger among older and lower-earning individuals
and typically involved a layoff but are present even in a mass-layoffs
sample. Disability insurance and out-migration yielded little income
replacement. These findings reveal that the Great Recession imposed
employment and income losses even after unemployment rates sig-
naled recovery.
I. Introduction
The US unemployment rate spiked from 5.0 percent to 10.0 percent over
the course of the Great Recession and then returned to 5.0 percent in
2015. However, the US employment rate (employment-population ratio)
I thank Patrick Kline, David Autor, David Card, Raj Chetty, Hilary Hoynes, Erik Hurst,
Lawrence Katz, Matthew Notowidigdo, Evan K. Rose, Jesse Rothstein, Emmanuel Saez, An-
toinette Schoar, Lawrence Summers, Till von Wachter, Owen Zidar, Eric Zwick, seminar
participants, and anonymous referees for helpful comments. Rose, Sam Karlin, and Carl
McPherson provided outstanding research assistance. I acknowledge financial support from
the Laura and John Arnold Foundation and the Berkeley Institute for Research on Labor and
Employment. This work is a component of a larger project examining the effects of tax expen-
ditures on the budget deficit and economic activity; all results based on tax data in this paper
are constructed using statistics in the updated SOI (Statistics of Income) Working Paper The
Electronically published September 13, 2019
[ Journal of Political Economy, 2019, vol. 127, no. 5]
© 2019 by The University of Chicago. All rights reserved. 0022-3808/2019/12705-0012$10.00
2505
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
did not exhibit similar recovery. Figure 1A shows that the employment
rate declined 3.6 percentage points between 2007 and 2015, as millions
of adults exited the labor force.
1
Population aging explains a minority of
the employment rate decline: weighting 2015 ages by the 2007 age distri-
bution reduces the decline to 2.0 percentage points, and the unadjusted
age 2554 employment rate declined by 2.6 percentage points. The de-
cline was concentrated among the low skilled (Charles, Hurst, and Noto-
widigdo 2016). The declines persistence contrasts with employment rate
recovery after earlier recessionsleading history-based analyses such as
Fernald et al. (2017) to doubt the possibility of employment hysteresis:the
Great Recession having depressed long-term employment despite the
unemployment recovery.
2
This paper tests whether the Great Recession and its underlying sources
caused part of the 200715 age-adjusted decline in US employment or
whether that decline would have prevailed even in the absence of the
Great Recession. It is typically difficult to test for long-term employment
impacts of recessions, for the simple reason that recession-independent
(secular) forces may also affect employment over long horizons (Ramey
2012). For example, the US employment rate rose by 2 percentage points
from the start of the 198182 recession to the late 1980s, as women con-
tinued to enter the labor force. In the context of the Great Recession, sec-
ular nationwide skill-biased shocks such as technical or trade changes
could have caused the entire 200715 employment decline, rather than
the recession.
I attempt to overcome this challenge by leveraging spatial variation in
Great Recession severity, along with data that minimize selection threats.
All US local areas by definition experienced the same secular nationwide
shocks, but some local areas experienced more severe Great Recession
shocks than other local areas. For example: Phoenix, ArizonaAmericas
sixth-largest cityexperienced a relatively large unemployment spike dur-
ing the Great Recession, while San Antonio, TexasAmericas seventh-
largest citydid not. A cross-area research design has the potential to dis-
tinguish recession impacts from secular nationwide shock impacts.
In the first part of the paper, I show, using public state-year aggregates,
that a cross-area research design is indeed fertile ground for studying the
labor market consequences of the Great Recession. Defining state-level
1
Variable definitions are standard and pertain to the age-16-and-over civilian noninsti-
tutional population.
2
This definition of hysterisis encompasses permanent impacts as well as transitory im-
pacts that last longer than elevated unemployment.
Home Mortgage Interest Deduction and Migratory Insurance over the Great Recession, ap-
proved under Internal Revenue Service (IRS) contract TIRNO-12-P-00374 and presented at
the National Tax Association. The opinions expressed in this paper are those of the author
alone and do not necessarily reflect the views of the IRS or the US Treasury Department. Data
and programs are provided as supplementary material online.
2506 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
shocks as 20079 employment growth forecast errors in an autoregressive
system (Blanchard and Katz 1992), I find that 2015 employment rates re-
mained low in the US states that experienced relatively severe Great Re-
cession shockseven though between-state differences in unemploy-
ment rates had returned to normal (and despite normal between-state
population reallocation). Hence, the cross-area patterns of employment,
unemployment, and labor force participation closely mirrored the aggre-
gate cross-time patterns of figure 1A. The persistent cross-area employ-
ment rate difference departs from the Blanchard-Katz finding of rapid re-
gional convergence.
The state-year evidence does not imply persistent employment impacts
of the Great Recession, because of two potential forms of cross-area com-
position bias: post-2007 sorting on labor supply and pre-2007 sorting on
human capital. First, severe Great Recession local shocks caused long-
term declines in local costs of living (Beraja, Hurst, and Ospina 2016),
which may have disproportionately attracted or retained those secularly
out of the workforce, such as the disabled and the retired (Notowidigdo
2011).
3
Even without such post-2007 sorting on labor supply, severe Great
Recession local shocks may have happened to hit areas with particularly
large preexisting concentrations of individuals affected by secular nation-
wide shocks. For example, the Great Recession disproportionately struck
local areas that had experienced housing booms (Mian and Sufi 2014) at-
tracting low- and middle-skill construction labor, and low- and middle-skill
laborers have been relatively adversely affected by secular nationwide
shocks in recent decades (e.g., Katz and Murphy 1992).
4
Under either type
of cross-area sorting, severe Great Recession local shocks may not have
caused local residents 2015 nonemployment.
I therefore turn for the second part of the paper to longitudinal linked
employer-employee data in order to control for prominent dimensions
of cross-area sorting. The longitudinal component allows one to measure
individuals employment over time regardless of whether and where in
the United States they migrateddirectly controlling for post-2007 sort-
ing on labor supply. The linked employer-employee component allows
one to control for fine interactions of age, 2006 earnings, and 2006 in-
dustryproxies for pre-2007 human capital.
Specifically, I draw a 2 percent random sample of individuals from de-
identified federal income tax records spanning 19992015. The main
3
For example, Warren Buffetts Advice to a Boomer: Buy Your Sunbelt Retirement
Home Now (Forbes, January 27, 2012; http://www.forbes.com/site s/janetnovack/2 012
/01/27/warren-buffetts-advice-to-a-boomer-buy-your-sunbelt-retirement-home-now/).
4
For example, You cant change the carpenter into a nurse easily ...monetary policy
cant retrain people (Charles Plosser in The Feds Easy Money Skeptic, Wall Street Jour-
nal, February 12, 2011; http://www.wsj.com/articles/SB1000142405274870470930457612
4132413782592).
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2507
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
FIG.1. Persistent employment rate declines after the Great Recession (pp: percentage
points). A, Data are from official seasonally adjusted BLS US labor force statistics from Jan-
uary 2007 through December 2015. The data are monthly and refer to the adult (161) ci-
vilian noninstitutional population. The vertical line denotes November 2007, the last
month before the Great Recession. For each outcome and month, the graph plots the cur-
rent value minus the November 2007 value, so that each data point in these series denotes a
percentage point change relative to November 2007. See online figure A.1 for age-adjusted
versions and versions restricted to 2554-year-olds. B, US states are divided into severely
(below-median) and mildly (above-median) shocked states, based on 20079 state-level
employment growth forecast errors in the autoregressive system of Blanchard and Katz
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
outcome of interest is employment at any point in 2015, equal to an indi-
cator for whether the individual had any W-2 earnings or any 1099-MISC
independent contractor earnings in 2015. The main sample is restricted
to those aged 3049 (working age) in 2007 in order to confine the 1999
2015 employment analysis to those between typical schooling and retire-
ment ages, and it is restricted to American citizens in order to minimize
unobserved employment in foreign countries. The analysis allows for
within-state variation by using the local-area concept of the commuting
zone (CZ): 722 county groupings that approximate local labor markets
and are similar to metropolitan statistical areas (MSAs) but span the en-
tire continental United States. I use the universe of information returns
to assign individuals to their January 2007 CZ. Each individuals Great Re-
cession local shock equals the percentage point change in her 2007 CZs
unemployment rate between 2007 and 2009 as recorded in the Bureau
of Labor Statistics (BLS) Local Area Unemployment Statistics (LAUS).
I obtain 2006 four-digit North American Industry Classification System
(NAICS) industry codes for half of 2006 W-2 earners by linking W-2s to
employers tax returns.
I find that, conditional on 2006 age-earnings-industr y fixed effects, a
1 percentage point higher Great Recession local shock caused the aver-
age working-age American to be 0.39 percentage points less likely to be
employed in 2015. The estimate is very statistically significant, approxi-
mately linear in shock intensity, robust across numerous specifications,
and large: those living in 2007 in largest-shock-quintile CZs were 1.7 per-
centage points less likely to be employed in 2015 than initially similar in-
dividuals living in 2007 in smallest-shock-quintile CZs. Placebo tests indi-
cate no relative downward employment trend in severely shocked areas
before the recession, corroborating identification. Controlling for 2015
local unemployment rates suggests that the incremental 2015 nonem-
ployment took the form of labor force exit rather than long-term unem-
ployment. I similarly find impacts on 2015 wage and contractor earnings:
23.6 percent (2$997) of the individuals preperiod earnings for every
1 percentage point higher shock.
One could be concerned that the foregoing within-industry analysis
fails to sufficiently control for pre-2007 sorting on human capital, as jobs
and therefore skill types in some industries are geographically differenti-
ated. Thus, as a novel robustness check, I approximate a within-job anal-
ysis, using a sample of 2006 workers at retail chain firms such as Walmart
(1992) estimated on 19762007 BLS LAUS state-year labor force statistics. For each out-
come and year, the graph uses LAUS to plot the unweighted mean in severely shocked
states, minus the same mean in mildly shocked states. Each series is demeaned relative to
its pre-2008 mean. See online appendixes A and B for more details.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2509
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
and Safeway that employ workers with similar skills to perform similar
tasks at similar salaries in many different local areas. Adding firm fixed ef-
fects in the retail sample attenuates the retail-sample employment effect
by 0.05 percentage points, or one-half of one standard error, to 20.36 per-
centage points, similar to the main estimate of 20.39 percentage points.
Certain comparisons suggest that the true average employment impact
could be closer to 20.30 percentage points per percentage point unem-
ployment rate shock. Naive extrapolation of the 20.30-for-1 and 20.39-
for-1 magnitudes would explain 5876 percent of the US 200715 working-
age annual employment rate decline as a long-term impact of the Great
Recession. The actual implied aggregate impact depends on general equi-
librium amplification or dampening.
The recessions impacts were highly uneven within local areas. The em-
ployment and earnings impacts were most negative for older individuals
and those with low2006 earnings. The latter pattern indicates thatthe Great
Recession induced a long-term increase in employment and earnings in-
equality across skill levels, not merely within skill levels across space. Im-
pacts do not appear smaller among mobile subgroups such as renters or
the childless.
Adjustment via migration and social insurance appears highly incom-
plete in replacing lost income. I find no statistically significant impact of
Great Recession local shocks on out-migration from ones 2007 CZ, and
earnings in other CZs did not replace any lost 2015 earnings relative to
those exposed to smaller Great Recession local shocks. Great Recession
localshockscausedsignificantlyhigherunemploymentinsurance(UI)ben-
efits 200810 before UI benefits expired and insignificantly higher So-
cialSecurityDisabilityInsurance(SSDI)benefitsinallyears. I estimate that
2015 SSDI replaced 2 percent of lost 2015 earnings, or up to 6 percent at
the 95 percent confidence upper bound.
Finally, I find that most of the 2015 incrementally nonemployed in se-
verely shocked areas had been laid off at some point during 200714 and
were nonemployed in the entire 201315 period. However, higher layoff
rates do not appear to explain the results, as the impacts hold within a
sample of laid-off individuals. In particular, I find equally large impacts
when comparing workers who were displaced in a 20089 mass layoff.
Hence, interactions with area-level economic conditions appear key to any
full explanation of the long-term impactssuch as human capital decay
during extended nonemployment or persistently low local labor demand.
The papers findings constitute evidence of long-term employment im-
pacts of the Great Recession (cf. Fernald et al. 2017) and add to a large lit-
erature on the incidence of labor market shocks. Earlier work had found
long-term impacts on individuals earnings (Topel 1990; Jacobson, La-
Londe, and Sullivan 1993; Neal 1995; Kahn 2010; Davis and von Wachter
2011) and sometimes on local areas employment rates (Blanchard and
2510 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Katz [1992] vs. Black, Daniel, and Sanders [2002] and Autor and Duggan
[2003]) and individuals employment rates (Ruhm [1991] and Walker
[2013] vs. Autor et al. [2014] and Jarosch [2015]). I provide evidence of
long-term impacts of Great Recession local shocks on individuals employ-
ment rates, likely via labor force exit. This evidence reinforces the view of
Autor and Duggan and a large literature dating back at least to Bowen and
Finegan(1969) and Phelps(1972)that transitoryadverseaggregateshocks
can have persistent negative employment impacts even after unemploy-
ment recovers.
The rest of the paper is organized as follows. Section II uses state-year
data to show that cross-area employment patterns mirrored aggregate
cross-time employment patterns 200715. Section III details the empiri-
cal design and longitudinal linked employer-employee data. Section IV
estimates overall impacts. Section V estimates impact heterogeneity. Sec-
tion VI investigates adjustment margins. Section VII documents layoff
and nonemployment trajectories. Section VIII discusses candidate mech-
anisms. Section IX concludes the paper.
II. Local Labor Markets Mirrored the Aggregate
This paper uses cross-area variation in Great Recession severity to test
whether the recession and its underlying sources caused part of the
200715 decline in the US employment rate displayed in figure 1A. I be-
gin by testing whether figure 1As aggregate cross-time employment pat-
terns have been mirrored across US local areas: did the local areas that
experienced severe Great Recession shocks also experience persistent
declines in employment and participation rates but not unemployment
rates, relative to mildly shocked areas? If so, then local labor markets may
indeed serve as a fruitful laboratory for understanding sources of aggre-
gate employment patterns.
A large literature has studied local labor market dynamics after local
employment shocks. The canonical analysis of Blanchard and Katz (1992)
found, in state-year data for 197690, that when a state experiences an ad-
verse employment shock, its population falls relative to trend but its un-
employment, participation, and employment rates return to parity with
those of other states in 56 years. That is, local shocks leave local areas
smaller but no less employed. This conclusion has been replicated in Eu-
ropean data (Decressin and Fatas 1995) and in a longer US state-year time
series (Dao, Furceri, and Loungani 2017). However, other papers have
found long-term participation and employment impacts of local shocks:
Black et al. (2002), Autor and Duggan (2003), and Autor, Dorn, and Han-
son (2013) found long-term impacts of specific types of US local shocks
on local SSDI enrollment, participation, and/or employment rates.
Hence, the existing literature presents a mixed picture.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2511
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
This section documents local labor market dynamics after Great Reces-
sion local employment shocks, with greater detail presented in online
appendixes B and C. For comparability to the broadest line of previous
work, I conduct this analysis at the state level and categorize states into
severely shocked states and mildly shocked states, using unforecasted
state-level changes in 20079 employment, derived from the autoregres-
sive system of Blanchard and Katz (1992). I estimate Blanchard and Katzs
log-linear autoregressive system in state employment growth, state unem-
ployment rates, and state participation rates in LAUS data for 19762007.
The LAUS data are the annual BLS LAUS series of employment, popula-
tion, unemployment, and labor force participation counts in 19762015
for 51 states (the 50 states plus the District of Columbia). Annual counts
are calendar year averages across months. I then compute 2008 and 2009
employment growth forecast errors for each stateequal to each statesac-
tual log employment growth minus the systems prediction for that state
and sum the tw o to obtain each states 20079 employment shock. Ro ughly
speaking, each states shock equals the states 20079 log employment
change minus the states long-run trend. Then, for expositional simplicity,
I group the 26 states with the most-negative shocks (e.g., Arizona) into the
severely shocked category and the remaining states (e.g., Texas) into the
mildly shocked category.
Figure 1B displays the 200315 time series of unemployment, partici-
pation, and employment rate differences between severely shocked states
and mildly shocked states. For each outcome and year, the graph plots the
unweighted mean among severely shocked states minus the unweighted
mean among mildly shocked states (the graph looks nearly identical
weighting by population). Within each series, I subtract the mean pre-
2008 severe-minus-mild difference from each data point, so each plotted
series has a mean of zero before 2008.
The figure shows that the unemployment rate in severely shocked states
relative to that in mildly shocked states spiked in 2008, peaked in 2009
10, and returned by 2015 to its mean prerecession severe-mild difference.
Yet the 2015 employment and participation rates in severely shocked
states remained 1.74 percentage points below the corresponding rates in
mildly shocked states, relative to the mean prerecession severe-mild dif-
ferences. The implied 2015 cross-area employment gap is large: 2.01 mil-
lion fewer adults were employed in severely shocked states than in mildly
shocked states, relative to full recovery to the prerecession severe-mild em-
ployment rate difference.
Hence, the cross-area (severe-minus-mild) patterns of unemployment,
participation, and employment of figure 1B do indeed broadly mirror
the aggregate cross-time (current-minus-2007) patterns of figure 1A.More-
over, in the same sense that the aggregate employment aftermath of the
Great Recession appears to contrast with the aftermath of the early-1980s
2512 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
and early-1990s recessions, so too does the cross-area aftermath of the
Great Recession appear to contrast with the cross-area aftermath of those
earlier recessions. Figure 2A repeats the employment rate series of fig-
ure 1B for the aftermath of the 1980s and 1990s recessions, treating the
early-1980s recessions as a single recession. The figure shows that cross-
state employment rates fully converged 4 years after the early-1990s reces-
sion and had converged by 1.65 percentage points (78 percent of the
t 5 0 divergence) 6 years after the early-1980s recession. Six-year conver-
gence aftertheGreatRecession wassmallerinbothabsoluteterms(0.85per-
centage points) and relative to the t 5 0 divergence (33 percent).
Blanchard and Katz(1992) suggest that the historical convergence mech-
anism is rapid population reallocation: a 21 percent state population
change relative to trend follows every 21 percent employment shock within
56 years.
5
Therefore,anatural possible explanationfor local employment
rate persistence after the Great Recession is that population reallocation
has slowed. Figure 2B investigates this possibility by plotting detrended
200714populationchangesequalto eachstates200714percentchange
inpopulationminusthe20007percent changein thestatespopulation
versus the states 20079 employment shock. The graph shows that popu-
lation reallocation after the Great Recession was similar to the historical
benchmark: each 21 percent 20079 employment shock was on aver-
age accompanied by a 21.016 percent (robust standard error: 0.260) de-
trended population change.
6
Figure 2C shows the same conclusion when
the original Blanchard-Katz time range197690, well before the recent
housing boomis used to estimate state-specific population trends in the
Blanchard-Katz system. Population in severely shocked states fell in 2007
15 relative to trend and relative to that of mildly shocked states, as much
as in the Blanchard-Katz benchmark.
To sum up, this section has found that aggregate 200715 cross-time
unemployment, participation, and employment rate patterns have been
mirrored in cross-area unemployment, participation, and employment
rate patterns over the same time period. Participation and employment
rates remained persistently low in the US states that experienced relatively
5
The unit elastic population response holds when reestimating the Blanchard and Katz
system on updated data for 19762015. The suggested causal chain is as follows: a state
(e.g., Michigan) experiences a one-time random-walk contraction in global consumer de-
mand for its locally produced traded good (e.g., cars), which induces a local labor demand
contraction and wage decline, which in turn induces a local labor supply (population) con-
traction, which then restores the original local wage and employment rate.
6
When not detrended, state population changes were largely uncorrelated with 20079
employment shocks, also shown in Mian and Sufi (2014) for the 20079 period only.
Blanchard and Katz (1992) find adjustment via population changes relative to trend. Gross
(out-)migration rates have declined modestly since 1980 (Molloy, Smith, and Wozniak
2011), but gross flows are still an order of magnitude larger than the net flows (population
reallocations) predicted by history in response to 20079 shocks.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2513
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
FIG.2. Great Recession local adjustment in comparison to history. A, States are divided
into severely (below-median) and mildly (above-median) shocked states based on the sum
of 2008 and 2009 employment growth forecast errors, as described in figure 1B,repeating
the process for the early-1980s recessions (198082, treated as a single recession) and the
early-1990s (199091) recession. Then, for each recession and year relative to the reces-
sion, the graph plots the unweighted mean LAUS employment rate in severely shocked
states, minus the same mean in mildly shocked states. Each series is demeaned relative
to its prerecession mean. For comparability across recessions, year 0 denotes the last reces-
sion year (1982, 1991, or 2009), while year 21 denotes the last prerecession year (1979,
1989, or 2007); intervening years are not plotted. Online figure A.5 plots analogous graphs
for labor force participation, unemployment, employment growth, and population growth.
The post-2001-recession experience exhibited incomplete convergence before being inter-
rupted by positively correlated 20079 shocks (not shown). B, This graph uses LAUS data
to plot detrended 2007 14 population changesequal to each states 200714 percent
change in population minus its 20007 percent change in populationversus the states
20079 employment shock. Overlaid is the unweighted best-fit line, with a slope of 1.016
(robust standard error of 0.260). C, The dotted lines plot Blanchard-Katz (1992) history-
based predictions (Pred.) for state-level responses to a 21 percent 20079 state-level em-
ployment shock, based on feeding the 197690-estimated Blanchard-Katz system a 2.41
percent employment shock followed by a 2.59 percent employment shock. The solid lines
plot mean actual (Act.) state-level responses based on reduced-form regressions of 200814
state-level outcomes on 20079 state-level shocks. See online appendix B for more details.
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
severe employment shocks 20079, even though unemployment rates con-
verged across space. Reduced population reallocation does not explain
the local persistence. The cross-area aftermath of the Great Recession de-
parts from the broad historical findings of Blanchard and Katz (1992),
but they accord with findings of Black et al. (2002), Autor and Duggan
(2003), and Autor et al. (2013) from specific contexts. I now turn to iden-
tifying whether Great Recession local shocks caused individuals to have
lower 2015 employment.
III. Isolating Impacts of Great Recession
Local Shocks
The previous section showed that local labor markets were microcosms
of aggregate employment patterns in 200715: 2015 employment rates
remained unusually low in US local areas that experienced an especially
severe 20079 employment shock. However, that cross-sectional fact does
not imply that individuals were nonemployed in 2015 because of where
they were living during the Great Recession, in light of two selection
threats. First, the disabled, retirees, and others secularly out of the labor
force may have disproportionately stayed in or moved to severely shocked
areas in order to enjoy low living costs while forgoing employment. Even
without selective migration on post-2007 labor supply, severely shocked
areas may have been disproportionately populated before the recession
by individuals who subsequently suffered large nationwide contractions
for their skill types, such as construction workers or routine laborers, that
would have occurred even in the absence of the recession. Under either
selection threat, the 2015 residents of severely shocked areas might be
nonemployed now regardless of geography.
This section specifies my empirical strategy for using longitudinal
linked employer-employee data to isolate causal effects of Great Reces-
sion local shocks on individuals 2015 employment; 2015 is the most re-
cent year of data available. Additional details are listed in online appen-
dixes D and E, including design foundations in potential outcomes.
A. Empirical Design
I adopt an empirical design that closely follows earlier work using longi-
tudinal individual-level data to estimate long-term impacts of labor mar-
ket shocks (e.g., Jacobson et al. 1993; Davis and von Wachter 2011; Autor
et al. 2014). I estimate regressions of the form
y
i2015
5 bSHOCK
ci2007ðÞ
1 v
gi2006ðÞ
1 e
i2015
, (1)
where y denotes an employment or related outcome, i denotes an indi-
vidual, SHOCK
c(i2007)
is the Great Recession shock to the individuals 2007
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2515
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
local area c, v
g(i2006)
denotes fixed effects for groups g of individuals de-
fined using individual pre-2007-determined characteristics, and e
i2015
is
a disturbance term. Here, b is the coefficient of interest: the causal effect
on ones 2015 outcomes of living in 2007 in a local area that experienced
a one-unit-larger Great Recession shock.
I interpret b as the causal effect of Great Recession local shocks and
their underlying sources, which are empirically indistinguishable,
7
and I
refer to this effect as the causal effect of Great Recession local shocks. Al-
ternative interpretations include b reflectin g differential prerecession trends
(e.g., a downward pre-2007 employment trend in severely shocked areas)
or independent correlated local shocks (e.g., post-2009 floods in severely
shocked areas). However, my interpretation of b is sensible because se-
verely shocked and mildly shocked areas exhibited relatively similar pre-
recession trends in the outcomes of interest (shown below in Sec. IV.A) and
because post-2010 unemployment rates converged monotonically across
severely shocked and mildly shocked areas. Moreover, adverse 2010
15 industry-based shift-share shocks are not positively correlated with ad-
verse Great Recession local shocks.
As in earlier work, the identifying assumption is selection on observ-
ables: individuals were as good as randomly assigned across local areas
within groups g. Also as in earlier work, I aim to satisfy this assumption, us-
ing rich longitudinal data to define groups finely along dimensions (e.g.,
age, prerecession earnings, and prerecession industry) that could be cor-
related with both Great Recession local shocks and omitted secular na-
tionwide shocks, and to restrict attention to subsamples in which the iden-
tifying assumption is particularly likely to hold. I use event study graphs
to evaluate potentially confounding prerecession trends.
B. Samples
I implement the pape rs empirical design by using selected deidentified
data from federal income tax records spanning 19992015. Iconstructthree
samples as follows. All three samples are balanced panels of individuals.
Main sample .The main sample comprises a 2 percent random sample
from what I call the full sample. The full sample comprises all American
citizens aged 3049 (working age) on January 1, 2007, who had not died
by December 31, 2015, and who had a valid payee ZIP code on at least one
information return that indicates continental US residence in January
7
For example, if the underlying source of Great Recession local shocks was persistent
local spending contractions (Mian, Rao, and Sufi 2013), then 2015 employment could
in principle be depressed because of layoffs during the Great Recession or because local
spending remained depressed through 2015, among other possibilities.
2516 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
2007.
8
The age restriction confines the 19992015 employment analysis to
those older than schooling age and younger than retirement age. Birth,
death, andcitizenship data are drawn from Social Security Administration
(SSA) records housed alongside tax records.
9
Restricting attention to
those alive in 2015 excludes analysis of mortality effects, likely a conserva-
tive choice (Sullivan and von Wachter 2009). I describe geocoded informa-
tionreturnsin the next subsection.I randomly sampleindividuals fromthe
full sample by using the last two digits of the individuals masked identifica-
tion number, yielding a main sample comprising 1,357,974 individuals.
Retail chain sample.The retail chain sample comprises individuals in
the full sample whose main employer in 2006 was a retail chain firm and
who lived outside the local area of the retail chain firms headquarters. It
is constructed as follows. For every individual in the full sample with a
2006 W-2 form, I attempt to link the masked employer identification num-
ber (EIN) on the individuals highest-paying 2006 W-2 to at least one busi-
ness return in the universe of business income tax returns 19992007.
10
I use the NAICS code on the business income tax return to restrict atten-
tion to workers whose 2006 firms operated in the two-digit NAICS retail
trade industries (44 or 45), for example, Walmart and Safeway.
11
I further
exclude employees living in 2007 in the CZ of their employers headquar-
ters, using the workers payee ZIP codes across their information returns
(see the next subsection) and the filing ZIP code on business income tax
returns and mapping these ZIP codes to CZs (the local-area concept de-
fined in the next subsection). Then, to identify CZs in which the 2006
firms operated, I further restrict thesample tofirms with at least 10 2006em-
ployees living in each of at least five CZs and then to the firms employees
living in 2007 in those CZs. This procedure yields a retail chain sample of
865,954 individuals at 524 retail firms.
12
8
In other contexts, working age sometimes refers to the age-1565 population. My
sample lies within ages 15 and 65 in all years 19992015. I refer to the sample as working
age mainly to communicate that it omits individuals beyond normal retirement age.
9
Citizenship is recorded as of December 2016. Results are very similar when not condi-
tioned on citizenship status. Conditioning on citizenship reduces the possibility that 2007
residents are employed in other countries but appear nonemployed in US tax data.
10
Many firms workers cannot be linked to a business income tax return; see the next
subsection.
11
Accessed data lacked firm names. I do not know which specific firms survived the
sample restrictions. These example firms and their industry codes were found on Yahoo
Finance.
12
As in other US administrative data (e.g., the Census Bureaus Longitudinal Employer
Household Dynamics; see Walker 2013), specific establishments of multiestablishment
firms are not directly identified in federal tax data. My process infers firms CZ-level oper-
ations from workers residential locations. The retail chain sample is smaller than the uni-
verse of retail chain workers for four main reasons: the age restriction, the de facto exclu-
sion of workers at independently owned franchises, mismatches between W-2 EIN and
business return EIN (see Sec. III.C.3 below), and removal of workers at firm headquarters.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2517
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Mass-layoffs sample.The mass-layoffs sample comprises all individuals
in the full sample who separated from an employer during a mass-layoff
event in either 2008 or 2009, after having worked for the employer during
the prior three calendar years inclusive of the separation year. It is con-
structed as follows, closely adhering to the sampling frame of Davis and
von Wachter (2011), except that I define an employer as an EIN-CZ pair
rather than an EIN; an EIN may represent a firm or a division of a firm.
Using the universe of W-2s and linking W-2 payee (residential) ZIP codes
to CZs, I compute annual employment counts at the EIN-CZ level. For an
employer to qualify as having a mass-layoff event in year t f2008, 2009g,
the employer must satisfy the following conditions: it had at least 50 em-
ployees in t 2 1; employment contracted by between 30 and 99 percent
from t 2 1tot 1 1; employment in t 2 1 was no greater than 130 percent
of t 2 2 employment; and t 1 2 employment was less than 90 percent of
t 2 1employment.
13
The mass-layoffs sample comprises all 1,001,543 in-
dividuals in the full sample who received a W-2 with positive earnings from
a mass-layoff employer in years t 2 2 through year t but not in t 1 1.
C. Variable Definitions
I now define variables. Year always refers to calendar year. Variables are
available for 19992015.
1. Outcomes
Similar to usage by Davis and von Wachter (2011) and Autor et al. (2014),
employment in a given year is an indicator for whether an individual has
positive Form W-2 earnings or Form 1099-MISC independent contractor
earnings (both filed mandatorily by the employer) in the year. Employ-
ment is thus a measure of having been employed at any time during the
year. Note that this annual employment measure differs from the conven-
tional point-in-time (survey reference week) measure used by the BLS. Al-
though not all self-employment is reported on 1099-MISCs, transition of
affectedworkerstoself-employmentlikelydoesnotexplaintheresults: Cur-
rentPopulationSurvey data indicatethatchanges in state self-employment
rates since 2007 were unrelated to changes in state formal employment
rates.
Earnings in a given year represents labor income and equals the sum of
an individuals Form W-2 earnings and Form 1099-MISC independent
13
The 99 percent threshold protects against EIN changes yielding erroneous mass-layoff
events. The last two criteria exclude temporary employment fluctuations. A firm that ini-
tially qualifies as having mass-layoff events in both 2008 and 2009 is assigned a 2008 event
only.
2518 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
contractor earnings. All dollar values are measured in 2015 dollars, ad-
justed for inflation using the headline consumer price index (CPI-U),
and are top-coded at $500,000 after inflation. DI receipt is an indicator for
whether the individual has positive SSDI income in the year as recorded
on Form 1099-SSA information returns filed mandatorily by the SSA. SSDI
is the main US disability insurance program. UI receipt is an indicator for
whether the individual has positive UI benefit income in the year as re-
corded on Form 1099-G information returns filed mandatorily by state
governments.
2. CZ and Great Recession Local Shock
Allowing for within-state variation, an individuals CZ is defined as her res-
idential commuting zone, a local-area concept used in much recent work
(Dorn 2009; Autor et al. 2014; Chetty et al. 2014). CZs are collections of
adjacent counties, grouped by Tolbert and Sizer (1996) using commuting
patterns in the 1990 census to approximate local labor markets. I calcu-
late, based on the 200610 American Community Surveys, that 92.5 per-
cent of US workers live in the CZ in which they work. Urban CZs are sim-
ilar to MSAs, but whereas MSAs exclude rural areas, every spot in the
continental United States lies in exactly one of 722 CZs.
The 2007 CZ is the CZ corresponding to the payee (residential) ZIP
code that appears most frequently for the individual in 2006 among the
approximately 30 types of information returns (filed mandatorily by insti-
tutions on behalf of an individual, including W-2s).
14
Information returns
are typically issued in January of the following year, so the ZIP code on an
individuals 2006 information return typically refers to the individuals
location as of January 2007. The 2015 CZ is defined analogously to the
2007 CZ, except that if an individual lacks an information return in 2014,
I impute CZ using informationreturnZIPcode from the most recently pre-
ceding year in which the individual received an information return. The
2007 state denotes the state with most or all of the 2007 CZs population.
Each individuals Great Recession local shock equals the percentage point
change in the individuals 2007 CZs unemployment rate from 2007 to
2009. Annual CZunemploymentrates are computed by aggregating monthly
population-weighted county-level unemployment rates from the monthly
BLS LAUS series to the CZ-month level, then averaging evenly within CZ-
years across months. Measuring local shocks in unitsof the unemployment
14
Numerous activities trigger information returns, including formal and independent
contractor employment, SSA or UI benefit receipt, mortgage interest payment, business
or other capital income, retirement account distribution, education and health savings ac-
count distribution, debt forgiveness, lottery winning, and college attendance. A compari-
son to external data suggests that 98.2 percent of the US population appeared on some
income tax or information return submitted to the IRS in 2003 (Mortenson et al. 2009).
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2519
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
rate change permits Section IV.Ds comparison to the aggregate shock,
which can be measured in the same units. Great Recession local shocks
are available on the authors website, along with data that can be used to
approximate the papers main result using publicly available data, as dem-
onstrated in online appendix table 1.
3. Covariates
Age is defined as of January 1 of the year, using date of birth from SSA
records housed alongside tax records. Female is an indicator for being re-
corded as female in SSA records. Following Autor et al. (2014), an indi-
vidual had high labor force attachment if she earned at least $10,382 in 2015
dollarsthe compensation for 1,600 hours of work at the 2004 federal
minimum wage in 2015 dollarsin each of the four years 20036. An in-
dividual had no labor force attachment if she had zero earnings in any year
20036. All other individuals had low labor force attachment. The term
1040 filer is an indicator for whether the individual appeared as either
a primary or secondary filer on a Form 1040 tax return in tax year 2006.
Married is an indicator for whether the individual was either the primary
or secondary filer on a married-filing-jointly or married-filing-separately
1040 return in tax year 2006. Number of kids equals the number of children
(zero, one, or two or more) living with the individual as recorded on the
individuals 2006 Form 1040 if the individual was a 1040 filer and zero oth-
erwise. Mortgage holder is an indicator for whether a Form 1098 informa-
tion return was issued on the individuals behalf by a mortgage servicer in
2006.
15
Birth state is derived from SSA records and, for immigrants, equals
the state of naturalization.
The 2006 industry equals the four-digit NAICS industry code on the
business income tax return of an individuals highest-paying 2006 Form
W-2, whenever a match can be made between the masked EIN on the W-2
and the masked EIN on the business income tax return. Four-digit NAICS
codes are quite narrow, distinguishing, for example, between restaurants
and bars. As displayed below in summary statistics and similar to recent
work (Mogstad, Lamadon, and Setzler 2017; Kline et al. 2018), almost half
of all W-2 earners could not be matchedlikely because the employer is
a government entity (which does not file an income tax return, covering
1520 percent of employment) or because the firm uses a different EIN
(e.g., a non-tax-filing subsidiary) to pay workers from the one that appears
on the firms tax return. For the construction of fixed effects, I assign in-
dividuals with a missing industry code to their own exclusive industry;
15
A mortgage servicer is required to file a Form 1098 on behalf of any individual from
whom the servicer receives at least $600 in mortgage interest on any one mortgage during
the calendar year.
2520 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
I assign non-W-2-earning contractors to their own exclusive industry; and
I assign the nonemployed to their own exclusive industry. I show below
that results are nearly unchanged when the sample is restricted to the
nonemployed and those with a valid W-2 industry, for whom the correct
industry is universally observed.
The 2006 age-earnings-industry fixed effects are interactions between age
(measured in one-year increments), 2006 industry, and 16 bins of the in-
dividuals 2006 earnings (in 2015 dollars inflated by the CPI-U) from the
individuals highest-paying employer.
16
The 2006 firm equals the masked
EIN on the individuals highest-paying 2006 W-2. The 2006 age-earnings-
firm fixed effects are constructed analogously to the 2006 age-earnings-
industry fixed effects. Other controls are used only for robustness checks
and are defined when used.
D. Summary Statistics
Table 1 reports summary statistics across the three samples. Of the main
sample, 79.1 percent were employed in 2015, with mean 2015 earnings
(including zeros and top-coded at $500,000) of $47,587; 6.2 percent re-
ceived SSDI income in 2015, and 25.6 percent received UI benefit in-
come in at least one of the years 200714. The sample is 49.3 percent fe-
male; 62.4 percent had high labor force attachment in 20036. The
average 2006 age is 39.9 years. The retail chain sample is on average more
female, less attached to the labor force, and less likely to be married. The
mass-layoffs sample is on average less female, more attached to the labor
force, less likely to be married, and more likely to have worked in construc-
tion or manufacturing in 2006 than the main sample. Industry in the main
sample is observed for 51.1 percent of W-2 earners. The average Great
Recession local shock was a 20079 increase in the local unemployment rate
of 4.6 percentage points, with a standard deviation of 1.5 percentage points.
Each of the three samples comprises roughly one million individuals.
Figure 3 displays a heat map of Great Recession local shocks. Familiar
patterns are apparent, such as severe shocks in certain manufacturing ar-
eas and Californias Central Valley but not along Californias coast. Of the
variation in Great Recession local shocks, 30.0 percent is statistically ex-
plained by the house pricedriven percent change in household net worth
in 20069 (Mian and Sufi 2009; correlation: 0.547). Recalling Section Is
example, PhoenixAmericas sixth-largest city, shown in the medium-
dark-shaded CZ in the middle of Arizonaexperienced a 77th percentile
16
The main result below is nearly identical when using Local CPI (consumer price in-
dex) 2the more aggressive of the Moretti (2013) local price deflatorsto locally deflate
2006 earnings before binning. Chosen to create roughly even-sized bins, the bin minimums
are $0, $2,000, $4,000, $6,000, $8,000, $10,000, $15,000, $20,000, $25,000, $30,000, $35,000,
$40,000, $45,000, $50,000, $75,000, and $100,000.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2521
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
TABLE 1
Summary Statistics
Main Sample Retail Chain Sample Mass-Layoffs Sample
Mean
(1)
Standard Deviation
(2)
Mean
(3)
Standard Deviation
(4)
Mean
(5)
Standard Deviation
(6)
Outcomes (in 2015):
Employed (%) 79.1 40.7 81.8 38.5 84.1 36.5
Earnings (2015 $) 47,587 63,784 33,381 44,557 48,204 62,830
UI receipt sometime 200714 (%) 25.6 43.6 28.3 45.0 52.2 50.0
DI receipt (%) 6.2 24.2 6.9 25.3 6.0 23.8
Personal characteristics (in 2006, 2007):
Female (%) 49.3 50.0 60.8 48.8 44.5 49.7
Age (years) 39.9 5.7 39.2 5.8 39.7 5.7
Aged 3034 (%) 22.2 41.5 27.0 44.4 23.8 42.6
Aged 3539 (%) 24.5 43.0 25.0 43.3 25.0 43.3
Aged 4044 (%) 26.0 43.9 24.3 42.9 25.5 43.6
Aged 4549 (%) 27.3 44.6 23.6 42.5 25.7 43.7
Earnings (2015 $) 45,652 55,122 33,424 36,708 52,511 55,336
No labor force attachment (%) 22.7 41.9 15.1 35.8 10.0 29.9
Low labor force attachment (%) 14.9 35.6 24.3 42.9 16.4 37.1
High labor force attachment (%) 62.4 48.4 60.6 48.9 73.6 44.1
Married (%) 62.8 48.3 52.2 50.0 52.9 49.9
0 children (%) 36.2 48.0 41.8 49.3 40.6 49.1
1 children (%) 22.6 41.8 22.9 42.0 23.4 42.3
21 children (%) 41.2 49.2 35.4 47.8 36.0 48.0
2522
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Mortgage holder (%) 38.3 48.6 25.9 43.8 38.4 48.6
Retail trade (NAICS 44,45; %) 5.2 22.3 100.0 .0 4.7 21.2
Construction/manufacturing (NAICS 23, 3133; %) 11.9 32.4 .0 .0 17.7 38.2
Other observed industry (%) 25.9 43.8 .0 .0 34.9 47.7
Contractor (%) 4.2 20.1 .0 .0 .0 .0
Nonemployed (%) 11.5 31.9 .0 .0 .0 .0
Great Recession local shock (pp) 4.6 1.5 4.8 1.5 5.0 1.5
No. of individuals 1,357,974 865,954 1,001,543
No. of 2007 CZs 722 655 667
Note.This table lists summary statistics for the papers three tax-data-based samples: the main sample (a 2 percent random sample), the retail chain
sample (all year-2006 nonheadquarters workers for identifiable retail chain firms), and the mass-layoffs sample (all workers who separated from a firm in a
2008 or 2009 mass layoff). All samples are restricted to American citizens aged 3049 on January 1, 2007, who had not died by December 31, 2015 and who
had a continental United States ZIP code in January 2007. Earnings is the sum of W-2 wage earnings and 1099-MISC independent contractor earnings in the
calendar year, in 2015 dollars and top-coded at $500,000. Employed is an indicator for having positive earnings. UI receipt sometime 200714 is an
indicator for having positive 1099-G unemployment insurance benefit income at some point in 200714. DI receipt is an indicator for having positive
1099-SSA disability insurance income in the calendar year. Age is measured on January 1, 2007. Labor force attachment is high if the individual had, in
every year 20036, earnings above 1,600 hours times the federal minimum wage, zero if the individual was nonemployed in any year 20036, and low oth-
erwise. Married is an indicator for filing a married-filing-jointly or married-filing-separately Form 1040 for tax year 2006. Children are dependent chil-
dren currently living with the individual as listed on the filed 1040 form. A 1040 filer is a primary or secondary filer on a 1040 form for tax year 2006. Dis-
played marriage and number-of-children statistics are restricted to 1040 filers; in regressions controlling for marriage or number-of-children fixed effects,
non-1040-filers are included as a separate group. Mortgage holder is an indicator for having positive mortgage payment listed on a Form 1098 in 2006
(mortgages held only in the name of a workers spouse or other third party are not included here). Industry categories are based on the NAICS code on the
business income tax return matched to the individual s highest-paying 2006 W-2 form. Nearly half of W-2 earners could not be matched, and individuals
who had only 1099-MISC independent contractor earnings are not matched; in fixed-effect regressions, unmatched 2006 W-2 earners, contractors, and the
nonemployed are assigned to three separate industries. The 2007 CZ derives from the individuals January 2007 residential ZIP code, as reflected most
commonly on her 2006 information returns. Great Recession local shock (pp: percentage points) equals the 2009 unemployment rate in the individuals
2007 CZ minus the 2007 unemployment rate in that CZ as reported in the BLS LAUS.
2523
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
FIG.3. Great Recession local shocks. This map depicts unweighted octiles (divisions by increments of 12.5 percentiles) of Great Recession local
shocks across commuting zones (CZs). CZs span the entire United States and are collections of counties that share strong commuting ties. Each
CZs shock equals the CZs 2009 LAUS unemployment rate minus the CZs 2007 LAUS unemployment rate. In the individual-level analysis, I assign
each individual to the Great Recession local shock of the individuals January 2007 CZ.
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
shock (6.0 percentage points), while San AntonioAmericas seventh-
largest city, shown in the large, faintly shaded, landlocked CZ in the
middle-bottom of Texasexperienced a 7th percentile shock (2.6 per-
centage points). The empirical analysis compares the 2015 outcomes of
individuals who were living in 2007 in places like Phoenix to initially sim-
ilar individuals who were living in 2007 in places like San Antonio.
IV. Overall Impacts
This section presents the papers main result: the estimated effect on
2015 employment of Great Recession local shocks. I begin by presenting
the main regression estimate visually and in table form, followed by ro-
bustness and extrapolation exercises.
A. Preferred Estimates
Figure 4A plots the time series of estimated effects of Great Recession lo-
cal shocks on employment. Each year ts data point equals
^
b from the fol-
lowing version of equation (1) estimated on the main sample:
e
it
5 bSHOCK
ci2007ðÞ
1 v
gi2006ðÞ
1 e
it
, (2)
where relative employment e
it
; EMPLOYED
it
2 ð1=8Þo
2006
s51999
EMPLOYED
is
is is change in mean binary employment status from pre-
recession years to year t,SHOCK
c(i2007)
denotes the Great Recession shock
to is 2007 CZ, and v
g(i2006)
denotes 2006 age-earnings-industry fixed ef-
fects. Measuring employment outcomes relative to each individuals pre-
recession mean transparently allows for baseline employment rate differ-
ences, similar to the relative cumulative earnings outcome of Autor et al.
(2014). The identifying assumption is that Great Recession local shocks
are as good as randomly assigned, conditional on age, initial earnings,
and initial industry. The sample and independent variable values are fixed
across figure 4As annual regressions; only the outcome varies from year
to year. The 95 percent confidence intervals are plotted in vertical lines
unadjusted for multiple hypotheses, based on standard errors clustered
by 2007 state.
The 2015 data point shows the papers main result: a 1 percentage
point higher Great Recession local shock (20079 spike in the CZ unem-
ployment rate) caused the average working-age American to be an esti-
mated 0.393 percentage points less likely to be employed in 2015. The
2015 impact of Great Recession local shocks is very significantly different
from zero, with a t-statistic of 4.1.
Figure 4B supports the linear specification of equation (2) by plotting
the underlying conditional expectation. It is constructed by regressing each
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2525
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
individualsGreatRecessionlocalshock on theage-earnings-industryfixed
effects, computing residuals, adding the mean shock to the residuals, or-
dering and binning the residuals into 20 evenly sized bins, and plotting
mean 2015 relative employment within each bin versus the bins mean re-
sidual. The displayed nonparametric relationship between 2015 relative
employment and Great Recession local shocks is largely linear.
FIG.4. Employment and earnings impacts of Great Recession local shocks. A, Regres-
sion estimates of the effect of Great Recession local shocks on relative employment, con-
trolling for 2006 age-earnings-industry fixed effects in the main sample. Each year ts out-
come is year t relative employment: the individuals year t employment (indicator for any
employment in t) minus the individuals mean 19992006 employment. The 95 percent con-
fidence intervals are plotted around estimates, clustering on 2007 state. For reference, the
2015 data point (the papers main estimate) implies that a 1 percentage point higher Great
Recession local shock caused individuals to be 0.393 percentage points less likely to be em-
ployed in 2015. B, This graph nonparametricall y depicts the relationship underlying the main
estimate. It is produced by regressing Great Recession local shocks on 2006 age-earnings-
industry fixed effects, computing residuals, adding back the mean shock level for interpre-
tation, and plotting means of 2015 relative employment within 20 equal-sized bins of the
shock residuals. Overlaid is the best-fit line, whose slope equals 20.393. C, This graph rep-
licates A for the outcome of relative earnings: the individuals year-t earnings minus the in-
dividuals mean 19992006 earnings.
2526 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Returning to figure 4A, the prerecession time series of estimated ef-
fects constitute placebo tests supporting the identifying assumption that,
conditional on controls, Great Recession local shocks were as good as ran-
domly assigned. In particular, the 19992006 point estimates do not dis-
play a downwardpretrend that would suggest a negative 2015 point estimate
even in the absence of Great Recession local shocks. The graph makes
other statistics possible. For example, the 19992006 point estimates aver-
age zero by construction, but one could prefer to benchmark the 2015 es-
timate to a subset of prerecession estimates such as those for 19992001;
when subtracting the 19992001 mean estimate from the 2015 estimate,
one obtains the still-large effect of 20.316. When subtracting the 2004
6 mean estimate, one obtains 20.507.
Table 2 displays coefficient estimates from equation (2) in the main
sample under various specifications. Column 4 corresponds to figure 4As
2015 data point, my preferred estimate. Columns 13 replicate the analysis
with coarser fixed effects and yield similar results, indicating relatively lit-
tle selection on the controlled dimensions among working-age Ameri-
cans. Column 5 displays ordered effect sizes by shock quintile, indicating,
for example, that living in 2007 in the most shocked quintile of CZs re-
sulted in the average individual being 1.75 percentage points less likely
to be employed in 2015 relative to living in 2007 in the least shocked quin-
tile. These effects are large, in that they are similar in magnitude to the
age-adjusted US employment rate decline 200715.
Full-year nonemployment indicates either long-term unemployment or
labor force nonparticipation (exit). Unemployment and participation
are not observed in tax data. To provide an indication of whether the non-
employment effects of Great Recession local shocks reflect labor force
exit, I test whether controlling for local unemployment persistence
equal to the CZs 2015 unemployment rate minus its 2007 unemployment
ratein the individuals 2007 CZ (col. 6) or 2015 CZ (col. 7) attenuates
the main estimate. This test can be viewed as co nservative: controlling for
epsilon-higher unemployment persistence in relatively severely shocked
areas could fully attenuate the main estimate without that unemployment
persistence being able to explain it quantitatively. In practice, the controls
in columns 6 and 7 slightly and insignificantly attenuate the main estimate
from 20.393 to 20.366 and 20.364, respectively. This suggests that most
and possibly all of the 2015 nonemployment impact of Great Recession
local shocks took the form of labor force exit, consistent with cross-state
patterns in figure 1B.
17
17
Local unemployment rates converged throughout 2015. When only the July
December period was used to define local unemployment persistence, the controls in
cols. 6 and 7 leave the estimate unchanged, at 20.392 and 20.393, respectively.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2527
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
TABLE 2
2015 Impacts of Great Recession (GR) Local Shocks: Outcomes Relative to Pre-2007 Mean
N 5 1,357,974
A. 2015 Employment (pp)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7)
GR local shock 2.412 2.425 2.417 2.393 2.366 2.364
(.112) (.112) (.099) (.097) (.089) (.089)
Most severely shocked quintile 21.746
(.471)
Fourth shock quintile 21.144
(.434)
Third shock quintile 2.793
(.356)
Second shock quintile 2.181
(.320)
Age FEs X
Age-earnings FEs X
Age-earnings-industry FEs XXXX
Unemployment persistence in 2007 CZ X
Unemployment persistence in 2015 CZ X
R
2
.00 .00 .01 .07 .07 .07 .07
Outcome mean 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.23
Absolute outcome mean 79.1 79.1 79.1 79.1 79.1 79.1 79.1
Standard deviation of GR local shocks 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49
Interquartile range of GR local shocks 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31
2528
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
B. Additional Outcomes and Controls
Cumulative Employment
200915 (pp)
Earnings in
2015 ($)
Cumulative Earnings
200915 ($)
Employed in 2015 (pp)
(8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13)
GR local shock 22.700 2997 26,212 2.364 2.480 2.378
(.516) (168) (919) (.100) (.133) (.112)
Rust CZ GR local shock .067 2.035
(.192) (.148)
Other CZ GR local shock .094
(.250)
Age-earnings-industry FEs X X X X X X
Manufacturing share X
R
2
.07 .11 .13 .07 .07 .07
Outcome mean 240.5 6,249 27,646 27.23 27.23 27.23
Absolute outcome mean 563.9 47,587 317,011 79.1 79.1 79.1
Standard deviation of GR local shocks 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49
Interquartile range of GR local shocks 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31
Note.All columns except col. 5 report coefficient estimates of the effect of Great Recession local shocks on postrecession outcomes in the main sample.
Column 5 divides individuals into quintiles based on their Great Recession local shocks and reports coefficients on indicators of shock quintiles, relative to the
least shocked quintile. Age fixed effects (FEs) are birth year indicators. Earnings FEs are indicators for 16 bins in the individuals 2006 earnings. Industry FEs
are indicators for the individuals 2006 four-digit NAICS industry. Local unemployment persistence equals the 2015 LAUS unemployment rate minus the 2007
LAUS unemployment rate in either the individuals 2007 CZ or the individuals 2015 CZ. The outcome in cols. 17 is 2015 relative employment: the individuals
2015 employment (indicator for any employment in 2015) minus the individuals mean 1999 2006 employment. The col. 8 outcome equals the sum of the
individuals 200915 employment minus seven times the individuals mean 19992006 employment. The col. 9 outcome equals the individuals 2015 earnings
minus the individuals mean 19992006 earnings. The col. 10 outcome equals the sum of the individuals 200915 earnings minus seven times the individuals
mean 19992006 earnings. Column 11 controls for the 2000 manufacturing share of employment in the individual s 2007 CZ, computed in County Business
Patterns. Columns 11 and 12 control for indicators (not shown) and interactions of a Rust-CZ indicator and an Other-CZ indicator, based on the individuals
2007 CZ. A Rust CZ is a CZ with an above-median manufacturing share; an Other CZ is a CZ with a below-median manufacturing share and an above median
20069 change in housing net worth from Mian and Sufi (2014). The absolute outcome mean equals the outcome mean before subtraction of the prerecession
mean. Standard errors (in parentheses) are clustered by 2007 state. For reference, col. 4 (the papers main specification) indicates that a 1 percentage point
higher Great Recession local shock caused individuals to be 0.393 percentage points less likely to be employed in 2015.
2529
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Figure 4C repeats figure 4A for the alternative outcome of relative
earnings: EARNINGS
it
2 ð1=8Þo
2006
s51999
EARNINGS
is
. Similar to figure 4As,
figure 4Cs coefficient estimates exhibit no consistent trend in the prere-
cession period and then fall persistently after the recession. Table 2, col-
umn 9, presents the graphs 2015 data point, which indicates that living
in 2007 in a CZ that experienced a 1 percentage point higher unemploy-
ment shock caused the average working-age American to earn 997 fewer
dollars in 2015.
18
Column 10 indicates that when cumulative relative earn-
ings o
2015
t52009
½EARNINGS
it
2 ð1=8Þo
2006
s51999
EARNINGS
is
are considered, the
effect size cumulates to 2$6,212 over the 7-year period 200915. Multi-
plied by the interquartile range of Great Recession shocks, this last point
estimate implies an average cumulative earnings loss of $14,352, uncondi-
tional on layoff or nonemployment.
Finally, traditional analyses conceive of the Great Recession as a fluc-
tuation that interrupted a long-run trend. However, it is possible that the
mid-2000s period was a positive masking fluctuation(Charlesetal.2016)
around a long-run secular decline in manufacturing employment (Charles,
Hurst, and Schwartz 2018) without extremely low unemployment rates.
In that case, this section would still identify 2015 employment impacts
of the masking-ending recession, and one may then interpret 2015 em-
ployment as being in line with a premasking trend.
I test for the manufacturing-driven unmasking interpretation of this
sections results in two ways. First, I use the Census Bureaus County Busi-
ness Patterns (CBP) for 2000 to compute each CZs manufacturing share
of employment. Column 11 repeats column 4, except that it controls for
the individuals 2007 CZs manufacturing share. The coefficient falls by
less than one-half of one standard error, to 20.364, and is still very statis-
tically significant.
19
Thus, the effect of Great Recession local shocks holds
within CZs with similar manufacturing shares. Second, for columns 12
13, I use the Mian and Sufi (2014) county-level measure of the 20069
changeinhousing net worth to compute each CZs 20069changeinhous-
ing net worth. I then group individuals into three bins according to their
2007 CZ: CZs with an above-median manufacturing share (Rust, since
many are in Rust Belt states), CZs with a below-median manufacturing
share and a below-median (i.e., especially adverse) change in housing
net worth (Sun, since many are in Sun Belt states), and Other CZs.
Column 12 repeats column 4, except that it includes an interaction of the
18
Fig. 6B scales this estimate by the individuals prerecession earnings. The earnings
analysis makes no correction for local cost-of-living changes. Measuring changes in local
living costs remains contentious, given the difficulty of measuring changes in local ameni-
ties (Moretti 2013) and a historical presumption that local amenities exactly offset appar-
ent cross-area real income differences (Rosen 1979; Roback 1982).
19
The coefficient is 20.358 when a quartic in the manufacturing share is controlled for.
2530 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Rust indicator and the Great Recession local-shock variable, an interaction
of the Otherindicatorandtheshock variable,andtheindicatorsseparately.
Column 13 repeats column 12, except without the Other indicator and in-
teraction. Both columns exhibit large and significant main effects of the
shock variable, indicating that the effect holds within Sun CZs and is not
driven only by Rust CZs. However, much room remains for manufacturing-
driven masking effects, including effects across industries and effects that
predated the recession or were otherwise not mediated by Great Recession
unemployment shocks.
B. Basic Robustness
Table 3 presents several robustness checks. Column 1 replicates the main
estimate, from table 2, column 4. Columns 25 control, respectively, for
individual-level characteristics that could independently determine labor
supply: gender, 2006 number of children, 2006 marital status, and 2006
home ownership fixed effects. In case residents of large or growing CZs
had different employment trajectories, column 6 controls for the individ-
uals 2007 CZ size, equal to the CZs total employment in 2006 as reported
in the CBP, while column 7 controls for the individuals 2007 CZs size
growth, equal to the CZs log change in CBP employment from 2000 to
2006. Column 8 controls for the individuals 2007 CZs share of workers
who work outside the CZ, computed from the 2006 10 American Com-
munity Surveys and motivated by recent work suggesting that commuting
options can attenuate local-shock incidence (Monte, Redding, and Rossi-
Hansberg 2015). As an early check of a policy mechanism, column 9 con-
trols for the individuals 2007 states maximum UI duration over years
200715, derived from Mueller, Rothstein, and von Wachter (2015). Col-
umn 10 similarly controls for the individuals 2007 states minimum wage
change 200715, using data provided by Vaghul and Zipperer (2016) and
used in Clemens and Wither (2014). The number of children, marriage,
and pre-2007 CZ size growth controls somewhat attenuate the main esti-
mate while others amplify it, and all estimates remain within one-half of
one standard error of the main estimate.
Nearly half of 2006 employees could not be matched to an industry code
(Sec. III.B). Column 11 confines the sample to the 2006 employees who
could be matched to an industry code and to the 2006 nonemployed. Col-
umn 12 further omits 2006 employees in constructionor manufacturing
two industries that could have disproportionately attracted workers (e.g.,
non-college-educated men) in severely shocked areas who might have ex-
perienced large employment declines evenin the absence of the recession
due to secular nationwide skill-biased change. Finally, severely shocked
CZs such as Phoenix had attracted many in-migrants in the decades lead-
ing up to 2007; if those in-migrants had somehow been negatively selected
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2531
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
TABLE 3
Robustness of the 2015 Employment Impacts
Employed in 2015: Outcome Relative to Pre-2007 Mean (pp)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9) (10) (11) (12) (13)
GR local shock 2.393 2.394 2.344 2.344 2.397 2.439 2.412 2.381 2.404 2.399 2.400 2.397 2.477
(.097) (.096) (.090) (.093) (.098) (.093) (.098) (.095) (.095) (.096) (.115) (.129) (.125)
Main controls XXXXXXXXXXXX X
Gender X
No. of children X
Married X
Home ownership X
CZ size X
CZ pre-2007 size growth X
Cross-CZ commuting X
Max UI duration 200715 X
Minimum wage change 200715 X
Exclude if invalid industry code XX
Exclude if construction/
manufacturing X
Instrumented with birth
state shock X
Observations 1,357,974 741,165 579,553 1,357,974
2532
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
R
2
.07 .08 .09 .08 .07 .07 .07 .07 .07 .07 .11 .10 .07
Outcome mean 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.23 27.20 26.69 27.23
Absolute outcome mean 79.1 79.1 79.1 79.1 79.1 79.1 79.1 79.1 79.1 79.1 73.9 70.8 79.1
Standard deviation of
GR local shocks 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49
Interquartile range of
GR local shocks 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31
Note.This table adds controls, sample restrictions, or instruments to the specification underlying table 2, col. 4, reprinted here in col. 1. Column 2 con-
trols for the individuals gender. Column 3 controls for the individuals 2006 number of children (fixed effects for 0, 1, or 21 children). Column 4 controls for
the individuals 2006 marital status. Column 5 controls for the individuals 2006 home ownership status. Columns 610 control for CZ-level characteristics.
Column 6 controls for the individuals 2007 CZ size, equal to the CZs total employment in 2006 as reported in the Census Bureaus County Business Patterns
(CBP). Column 7 controls for the individuals 2007 CZ size growth, equal to the CZs log change in CBP employment from 2000 to 2006. Column 8 controls for
the individuals 2007 CZs share of workers who work outside the CZ, computed from the 200610 American Community Surveys. Column 9 controls for the
individuals 2007 state s maximum unemployment insurance duration over years 200715. Column 10 controls for the individuals 2007 states 2015 minimum
wage minus that states 2007 minimum wage. Column 11 excludes 2006 W-2 earners without an industry code and 2006 contractors and thus restricts the sam-
ple to those for whom the 2006 industry is correctly measured: 2006 W-2 earners with a valid industry code and the 2006 nonemployed. Column 12 further
excludes individuals employed in construction or manufacturing in 2006. Column 13 instruments the individuals Great Recession local shock, using the mean
of the Great Recession local shock in the individuals birth state. Standard errors (in parentheses) are clustered by 2007 state.
2533
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
on future labor productivity or other employment determinants, condi-
tional on the main controls, the main estimate could be confounded. Col-
umn 13 addresses this concern by instrumenting one s Great Recession
local shock using the mean Great Recession local shock in the individu-
als birth state. None of these specifications attenuates the main point
estimate.
C. Within-Job Robustness
The above estimates of the 2015 impact of Great Recession local shocks
control for age-earnings-industry fixed effects. Those estimates will be bi-
ased if there was secular nationwide skill-biased change in 200715 and if
skill differed across space within age-earnings-industry bins in a correlated
way with Great Recession local shocks. To address this possibility, figure 5A
and table 4 attempt to better approximate within-skill estimates by con-
trolling for age-earnings-firm fixed effects in the retail chain sample. The
motivation is thatunlike firms in manufacturing and other industries
retail chain firms such as Walmart and Starbucks employ workers with
similar skills to perform the same job at similar earnings in many local
areas.
20
The retail chain sample comprises working-age workers who in
2006 worked at a retail chain firm in a local area outside the firms cor-
porate headquarters. To the extent that age-earnings-firm bins proxy for
jobs across space and that skill selection into jobs is similar across space,
estimates controlling for age-earnings-firm fixed effects in the retail chain
sample will mitigate skill selection threats. I refer to such estimates as within-
job estimates.
Figure 5A repeats figure 4A in the retail chain sample and with 2006
age-earnings-firm fixed effects.
21
Figures 5A and 4A show broadly similar
time series patterns and point estimates. In the retail chain sample, I es-
timate that a 1 percentage point higher Great Recession local shock re-
sulted in the average working-age American being 0.359 percentage
points less likely to be employed in 2015similar to the 0.393 percentage
point estimate in the main sample. Thus, the main result is robust to the
within-job specification.
Table 4 repeats table 2 for the retail chain sample and with specifica-
tions using 2006 age-earnings-firm fixed effects. Column 5 displays the
20
In contrast, e.g., Boeing employs workers with strong writing skills in Virginia in order
to manage government contracts and employs workerspossibly of the same age and at
the same annual earningswith strong manufacturing skills in Washington State in order
to build airplanes.
21
Table 1 showed that the main and retail chain samples differ demographically, and
the next section finds impact heterogeneity across demographic groups. I therefore re-
weight the retail chain sample to match the main sample, as in DiNardo, Fortin, and Le-
mieux (1996), along 2007 CZ, gender, 5-year age bin, and 2006 earnings bins, as defined
below in fig. 6.
2534 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
FIG.5. Employment impacts in special samples. A, This graph replicates figure 4A in
the retail chain sample (all year-2006 nonheadquarters workers for identifiable retail chain
firms), with 2006 age-earnings-firm fixed effects instead of 2006 age-earnings-industry fixed
effects. The retail chain sample is reweighted to match the main sample as in DiNardo et al.
(1996), along 2007 CZ, gender, 5-year age bin, and 2006 earnings bins as defined in figure 6.
Each fully interacted cell with overlap in both samples receives the same total weight in the
retail sample as in the main sample; the 0.02 percent of retail chain sample observations
with no overlap receive zero weight. Reweighting nearly halves the impact of firm fixed ef-
fects (the difference between cols. 4 and 5 of table 4) and negligibly affects the final point
estimate. B, This graph replicates figure 4A in the mass-layoffs sample (all workers who sep-
arated from a firm in a 2008 or 2009 mass layoff), also reweighted to match the main sam-
ple, as above, with a negligible effect on the final point estimate. See the figure 4A legend
for specification details.
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
TABLE 4
2015 Impacts of Great Recession (GR) Local Shocks, Retail Chain Sample: Outcome Relative to Pre-2007 Mean
N 5 865,954
A. Main Specifications: Employed in 2015 (pp)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
GR local shock 2.414 2.426 2.398 2.407 2.359 2.340 2.339
(.118) (.119) (.102) (.094) (.080) (.063) (.061)
Most severely shocked quintile 21.496
(.308)
Fourth shock quintile 21.416
(.298)
Third shock quintile 2.968
(.288)
Second shock quintile 2.366
(.298)
Age FEs X
Age-earnings FEs X
Age-earnings-industry FEs X
Age-earnings-firm FEs XXXX
Unemployment persistence in 2007 CZ X
Unemployment persistence in 2015 CZ X
R
2
.00 .00 .02 .03 .07 .15 .15 .15
Outcome mean 29.80 29.80 29.80 29.80 29.80 29.80 29.80 29.80
Absolute outcome mean 81.8 81.8 81.8 81.8 81.8 81.8 81.8 81.8
Standard deviation of GR local shocks 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49
Interquartile range of GR local shocks 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31
2536
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
B. Additional Outcomes and Controls
Cumulative Employment
200915 (pp)
(9)
Earnings
in 2015 ($)
(10)
Cumulative Earnings
200915 ($)
(11)
Employed in 2015 (pp)
(12) (13) (14)
GR local shock 22.504 2422 22,777 2.365 2.589 2.405
(.430) (134) (606) (.081) (.111) (.095)
Rust CZ GR local shock .258 .069
(.144) (.115)
Other CZ GR local shock .414
(.251)
Age-earnings-firm FEs X X X X X X
Manufacturing share X
R
2
.15 .21 .23 .15 .15 .15
Outcome mean 251.5 2,356 8,381 29.80 29.80 29.80
Absolute outcome mean 590.0 33,381 225,554 81.8 81.8 81.8
Standard deviation of GR local shocks 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49 1.49
Interquartile range of GR local shocks 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31 2.31
Note.This table replicates table 2 in the retail chain sample. See the note to that table for details. Firm is an indicator for the individuals 2006 firm (a
retail chain firm). The retail chain sample is reweighted to match the main sample, as described in the fig. 5 legend.
2537
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
2015 point estimate from figure 5A. Relative to column 4s estimate con-
trolling only for age-earnings-industry fixed effects, one sees that the firm
fixed effects attenuate the point estimate by 11.8 percent, or one-half of
one standard error.
22
If the papers main estimate of 20.393 is overstated
by 11.8 percent, then the true main-sample effect size would be 20.347.
The retail chain samples earnings effects are smaller than those in the
main sample, though 2015 mean earnings are also smaller in the retail
chain sample. Overall, results are similar across the main and retail chain
samples.
D. Extrapolation
I close the section with a simple extrapolation of the 2015 employment
impact of Great Recession local shocks to the 2015 employment impact
of the Great Recession aggregate shock. The exercise adopts the strong
naive assumption that the impact of the Great Recession aggregate
shock on national residents is identical to the impact of a proportionally
sized Great Recession local shock on initial local residents, as in similar
work (e.g., Charles, Hurst, and Notowidigdo 2015). I find that simple ex-
trapolation suggests that the Great Recession caused 76 percent of the
postrecession age-adjusted decline in the working-age US employment
rate as measured in this paper (any annual employment of the birth co-
horts aged 3049 in 2007).
The extrapolation estimate of 76 percent derives from three inputs.
First, the aggregate US unemployment rate increased by 4.63 percentage
points from 2007 to 2009. Second, table 2, column 4, reported that expo-
sure to a 1 percentage point higher local unemployment spike 20079 in-
duced a 0.393 percentage point decline in any 2015 employment. Based
on these two inputs, simple extrapolation suggests a 1.82 (4:63 0:393)
percentage point decline in the US working-age employment rate be-
cause of the Great Recession.
Third, the employment rate decline of these birth cohorts through
2015, 7.23 percentage points (table 2), was 2.40 percentage points larger
than the decline that would have been expected because of aging, based
on analogous earlier cohorts through years 20037. Specifically, recall
that 27:23 5 De
2015
, where De
t
; E½EMPLOYED
it
jcðiÞ C
t
2 ð1=8Þo
t29
s5t216
E½EMPLOYED
is
jcðiÞ C
t
andthatC
t
isthesetofworking-agebirthcohorts
ft 2 58, , t 2 39g. These cohorts would have experienced an employ-
ment rate decline due to aging even in the absence of the recession. I
quantify the aging effect by using employment rates of analogous earlier
working-age cohorts through years 20037asð1=5Þo
2007
t52003
De
t
524:83,
22
Introducing firm fixed effects increased the effect magnitude in an earlier versions
specifications.
2538 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
based on the Current Population Surveys Annual Social and Economic
Supplement (ASEC) in lieu of tax data availability before 1999. The age-
adjusted working-age employment rate decline was therefore 2.40 (7:232
4:83) percentage points. Hence, simple extrapolation suggests that the
GreatRecessioncaused76percent(1.82/2.40)oftheage-adjusteddecline.
23
It is important to note that the actual impact may be more or less than
76 percent. First, there is statistical and specification uncertainty in the
2015 impact of Great Recession local shocks. Sections IV.A and IV.C de-
scribed scenarios in which one could believe that the true effect size was
closer to 0.3. When 0.300 is used instead of 0.393, the share explained by
the recession is 58 percent. Second, there is extrapolative uncertainty be-
cause of general equilibrium considerations (Nakamura and Steinsson
2014; Beraja et al. 2016). A shock to one local area can have a larger local
impact than a proportionately sized aggregate shock, for example, because
production can more easily shift across local areas than across countries.
Alternatively, the impact of an aggregate shock may exceed the impact of
a proportionately sized local shock on initial local residents, for exam-
ple, to the extent that initial local residents escaped or dampened local-
shock impacts by migrating to other local areas (Blanchard and Katz
1992) more than to other countries.
V. Impact Heterogeneity
This section analyzes impact heterogeneity across individuals. An active
literature in labor economics studies determinants of wage earnings in-
equality within (e.g., Card, Heining, and Kline 2013) and across (e.g.,
Autor, Katz, and Kearney 2008) worker types. The previous section found
that Great Recession local shocks caused 2015 wage earnings inequality
within worker types: initially similar workers experienced different 2015
employment and earnings outcomes after exposure to different Great Re-
cession local shocks. Figure 6 explores effects of Great Recession local
shocks on inequality across worker types.
Figure 6A displays employment impact heterogeneity. The figures first
five rows plot point estimates and 95 percent confidence intervals of the
2015 employment impact of Great Recession local shocks overall in the
main sample (reprinting the main estimate from table 2, col. 4) and in
each of four 2006 earnings bins, a common proxy for broad initial skill
level (e.g., Autor et al. 2014). I find that low initial earners bore more of
the employment incidence of Great Recession local shocks, suggesting
23
Note that the age-adjusted decline of 2.40 percentage points is similar to the age-
adjusted declines in headline BLS point-in-time employment rates reported in the intro-
duction. To account for modest age distribution differences related to the baby boom,
cohorts underlying the computation of ð1=5Þo
2007
t52003
De
t
are reweighted to match the
working-age distribution for t 5 2015, as written in the appendix below.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2539
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
FIG.6. Impact heterogeneity. A, Coefficients and 95 percent confidence intervals (clus-
tering by 2007 state) of the impact of Great Recession local shocks on 2015 relative employ-
mentoverall and by subgroup. All estimates derive from the specification underlying fig-
ure 4As 2015 data point, corresponding here to the overall row. Subgroup estimates restrict
the sample to the specified subgroup defined by 2006 earnings, 20036 labor force (LF) at-
tachment, 2007 age, gender, 2006 marital status, 2006 number of children, or 2006 mort-
gage holding. Non-1040-filers are classified here as single and childless. Subgroup migration
rates are superimposed on the right. Migration is defined as ones 2015 CZ being different
from ones 2007 CZ. B, Replication of A for 2015 earnings, expressed in multiples of mean
annualearnings19992006:2015 earnings divided bymean annual 19992006 earnings. This
quantity is top-coded at the 99th percentile: individuals with zero 19992006 earnings are
assigned the top code if 2015 earnings were positive and assigned 0 otherwise. The overall es-
timate is 23.55 (standarderror: 0.94), implying that a 1 percentage point higher Great Reces-
sion local shock reduced the average individuals 2015 earnings by 3.55 percent of her prere-
cession earnings.
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
that those shocks increased employment inequality across workers of dif-
ferent initial skill levels. Low initial earners (defined as those who earned
less than $15,000 in 2006, approximately the 33rd percentile in this sam-
ple) experienced a worse than average impact, while high initial earners
(defined as those who earned more than $45,000 in 2006, approximately
the 67th percentile) experienced a better-than-average impact. This cross-
area finding mirrors the earlier cross-time finding that aggregate em-
ployment declines since 2007 were concentrated among the least skilled
(Hoynes, Miller, and Schaller 2012; Charles et al. 2016). The subsequent
three rows suggest worse-than-average impacts among individuals with
less labor force attachment (Autor et al. 2014).
Figure 6B displays similar patterns for earnings. I analyze proportional
earnings changes in order to parallel earlier work on earnings inequality
studying earnings ratios, such as the ratio of the 90th and 50th percentiles
(Autor et al. 2008). Analogous to that of Autor et al. (2014), the outcome
in each regression is the ratio of 2015 earnings to mean annual pre-
2007 earnings with no local cost-of-living adjustments: EARNINGS
i2015
=
ð1=8Þo
2006
s51999
EARNINGS
is
.
24
The overall estimate indicates a large impact
of Great Recession local shocks on proportional earnings: a 1 percentage
point higher Great Recession local shock reduced the average individu-
als 2015 earnings by 3.55 percent of her prerecession earnings. The sub-
group analysis reveals relatively similar proportional earnings declines
across subgroups, except by initial earnings and labor force attachment
subgroups, where low initial earners and less-attached individuals experi-
enced larger declines. Hence, both employment and earnings analyses
suggest that Great Recession local shocks increased inequality across work-
ers of different initial skill levels.
The remaining rows of figure 6 display impact heterogeneity by gen-
der, 2007 age group, 2006 marital status, 2006 number of children, and
2006 mortgage holding status. I find larger employment effects among
older individuals than among younger individualsconsistent with pre-
vious work suggesting that older workers are less resilient to labor market
shocks ( Jacobson et al. 1993).
Finally, one may expect that migration rate heterogeneity explains im-
pact heterogeneity, in light of the lesson from Blanchard and Katz (1992)
that population reallocation equilibrates US local labor markets. Figure 6
lists migration ratesdefined as the share of individuals with a 2015 CZ
different from their 2007 CZfor each subgroup of individuals to the
right of the subgroup-specific impacts. There is no consistent correla-
tion between migration rates and estimated Great Recession local-shock
24
This quantity is very right skewed and therefore top coded at the 99th percentile. In-
dividuals with zero 19992006 earnings are assigned the top code if 2015 earnings were
positive and are assigned 0 otherwise.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2541
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
impacts. For example, nonmortgage holders had an 18 percent migra-
tion rate, while mortgage holders had a 13 percent migration rate; yet,
if anything, nonmortgage holders appear to have experienced larger im-
pacts. The next section further explores adjustment via out-migration.
VI. Adjustment Margins
This papers rich administrative data allow me not only to estimate long-
term employment and earnings impacts but also to estimate year-by-year
adjustments across space and onto social-insurance programs. Table 5 an-
alyzes year-by-year adjustment margins. Each cell lists the coefficient and
standard error on the Great Recession local-shock variable from a sepa-
rate regression in the main analysis sample with the main controls (2006
age-earnings-industry fixed effects), varying only the outcome. Column 1
reproduces the 200715 employment estimates plotted in figure 4A. Col-
umn 2 analyzes migration, using a binary outcome equal to one if and only
if an individuals residential CZ in the year was different from her 2007
CZ. The estimates indicate that individuals who experienced more severe
Great Recession local shocks were insignificantly (0.073 percentage points)
more likely to have moved after 2007 relative to the overall migration rate
of 16 percent, suggesting that out-migration was not a major adjustment
margin.
Columns 3 and 4 further support that conclusion by disaggregating the
annual employment results of column 1 into two types of annual employ-
ment: employment inside the individuals 2007 CZ and employment out-
side the individuals 2007 CZ, similar to Autor et al. (2014).
25
Unsurpris-
ingly, given the main effect of column 1, column 3 shows that individuals
subject to more severe Great Recession local shocks were significantly less
likely to be employed in their 2007 CZs in 2015. But column 4 shows that
these individuals were insignificantly less likely to be employed outside
their 2007 CZs as well. Columns 57 show analogous results for earnings.
Column 7 shows a marginally significant negative effect of Great Reces-
sion local shocks on out-of-2007-CZ earnings in 2015, implying no replace-
ment of lost 2015 within-initial-CZ earnings with earnings in other CZs at
the 95 percent confidence upper bound.
The lack of an out-migration response may besurprising, giventhe find-
ing of Section II that population fell relative to trend in severely shocked
states and by the same large magnitude predicted by Blanchard and Katz
(1992). However, population reallocation is consistent with substantially
25
That is, the col. 3 outcome for a year t equals ð1 2 MOVED
it
Þ EMPLOYED
it
2
ð1=8Þo
2006
s51999
EMPLOYED
is
,whereMOVED
it
(the col. 2 outcome) equals one if cðitÞ cði2007Þ
and zero otherwise. The col. 4 outcome for a year t equals MOVED
it
EMPLOYED
it
2 ð1=8Þo
2006
s51999
EMPLOYED
is
.
2542 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
TABLE 5
Time Series of Adjustment Margins
Outcome (Relative or Absolute)
Employed
(pp)
(1)
Migrated outside
2007 CZ
(pp)
(2)
Employed
in 2007 CZ
(pp)
(3)
Employed outside
2007 CZ
(pp)
(4)
Earnings
($)
(5)
Earnings
in 2007 CZ
($)
(6)
Earnings outside
2007 CZ
($)
(7)
UI
Income
($)
(8)
SSDI
Income
($)
(9)
Effect in 2007 .087 .000 .087 .000 2205 2205 0 14.3 23.8
(.106) (.106) (115) (115) (12.2) (8.9)
Effect in 2008 2.099 .036 2.098 2.001 2508 2480 228 36.3 23.4
(.079) (.119) (.077) (.006) (108) (108) (11) (15.6) (9.4)
Effect in 2009 2.349 .109 2.321 2.028 2750 2687 263 94.0 .5
(.080) (.208) (.077) (.012) (129) (127) (18) (32.1) (11.8)
Effect in 2010 2.403 .209 2.367 2.037 2807 2736 271 83.9 2.6
(.074) (.272) (.074) (.017) (131) (125) (30) (32.1) (13.0)
Effect in 2011 2.387 .248 2.339 2.048 2840 2745 2
94 43.1 7.5
(.072) (.296) (.071) (.022) (119) (105) (35) (24.3) (13.7)
Effect in 2012 2.373 .244 2.324 2.049 2890 2784 2106 19.9 9.8
(.075) (.334) (.076) (.026) (141) (117) (45) (20.1) (15.2)
Effect in 2013 2.434 .180 2.365 2.069 2960 2810 2149 7.7 13.0
(.089) (.382) (.091) (.032) (147) (108) (56) (16.3) (17.0)
Effect in 2014 2.360 .134 2.322 2.038 2968 2799 2169 23.0 15.7
(.100) (.422) (.101) (.031) (197) (135) (84) (9.9) (17.7)
Effect in 2015 2.393 .073 2.338 2.055 2997 2786 2211 25.9 19.6
(.097) (.456) (.100) (.042) (168) (108) (101) (8.9) (18.8)
Note.This table expands on the specifications of table 2, cols. 4 and 9, whose results are reprinted here in the bottom rows of cols. 1 and 5, respec-
tively. Each cell reports the coefficient on the Great Recession local-shock variable from a separate regression in which the outcome uses the postrecession
year indicated in the row, instead of exclusively using 2015, as in table 2. Every regression uses the same 1,357,974 observations underlying table 2. The
col. 1 outcome of relative employment is defined in table 2, varying the postrecession year between 2007 and 2015. The col. 2 outcome is an indicator for
out-migration, equal to the individuals year-f CZ being different from her 2007 CZ. Columns 3 and 4 separate the col. 1 outcome for year f into two
outcomes: employment in year f in the individuals 2007 CZ and employment in year f outside the individuals 2007 CZ, each minus mean 1999
2006 employment. The col. 5 outcome is defined in table 2. Columns 7 and 8 separate the col. 5 outcome analogously to cols. 34. The col. 8 outcome
is the individuals unemployment insurance benefits in year f. The col. 9 outcome is the individuals Social Security Disability Insurance benefits in year f.
Standard errors (in parentheses) are clustered by 2007 state. See online appendix table 2 for pretrends.
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
reduced in-migration rather than substantially increased out-migration
(Monras 2015). Autor et al. (2014) similarly find that out-migration was
not a major margin of adjustment to import competition. I leave to other
work why more individuals did not out-migrate or where they migrated
(Yagan 2014).
Columns 8 and 9 study adjustment via social-insurance transfer pay-
ments: UI benefits and SSDI benefits.
26
Unsurprisingly, individuals ex-
posed to larger Great Recession local shocks received significantly higher
mean UI benefits in 2008 10 than those exposed to smaller local shocks.
However, Great Recession UI benefits soon expired, and these individu-
als higher mean UI benefits declined after 2010 to insignificantly lower
UI benefits by 2015. Column 9 shows that individuals subject to Great Re-
cession local shocks accumulated rising, though insignificantly higher,
SSDI benefits relative to those subject to smaller Great Recession local
shocks. Comparing the sum of the 200715 UI and SSDI income coeffi-
cients to the sum of the column 5 earnings coefficients, one estimates that
elevated UI and SSDI transfer payments replaced 5.1 percent of lost earn-
ings: 4.2 percent from UI and 0.9 percent from SSDI. Focusing only on
2015 SSDI income, one estimates that it replaced 2.0 percent (19.6/997)
of lost 2015 earnings, rising to 5.6 percent at the 95 percent confidence
upper bound.
27
Thus, observed transfer payments far from fully compen-
sated for the negative earnings effects.
28
SSDI has been found to be an important margin of adjustment to labor
market shocks (Autor and Duggan 2003; Autor et al. 2013, 2014). Expand-
ing on table 5s null SSDI results, table 6, column 1, replicates the papers
main specification for the binary outcome of SSDI receipt in 2015. I find
a moderate and insignificant estimated impact, though with substantial
uncertainty: a point estimate of 0.071 percentage points and a standard
error of 0.145 percentage points, relative to the employment impact of
20.393 percentage points.
More thoroughly, one can estimate the share of the incrementally non-
employed in severely shocked areas who were on SSDI in 2015. Table 6,
26
UI provides temporary cash benefits to laid-off workers who had earned above a min-
imum threshold in the quarters preceding layoff. SSDI provides typically permanent (until
retirement age) cash and medical benefits to individuals with at least 5 years of work history
in the 10 years before the individual developed a long-lasting medical condition deemed to
prevent substantial employment.
27
To estimate the upper bound, I regress 2015 SSDI on 2015 relative earnings instru-
mented with Great Recession local shocks, controlling for 2006 age-earnings-industry fixed
effects and clustering on 2007 state. The coefficient on 2015 relative earnings is 20.020,
with a standard error of 0.018.
28
Spousal labor supply was likely also a ver y incomplete adjustment margin: the shocks
studied here are measured as CZ-wide shocks, both genders and marital statuses suffered
large impacts (fig. 6), and earlier work in similar data showed that wives replaced only
5.6 percent of males lost income after layoff (Hilger 2016).
2544 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
column 2, estimates the effect of Great Recession local shocks on a new
outcome similar to that of Lee (2009): an indicator for whether the worker
was employed in 2015 or received SSDI in 2015, m inus mea n employ -
ment 19992006.
29
Table 6, column 2, reports that Great Recession lo-
cal shocks had a significant negative effect, 20.265 percentage points,
on the employed-or-SSDI outcome, suggesting that 32.6 percent (12
ð20:265=20:393Þ) of the incrementally nonemployed received SSDI in
2015. However, the standard errors are substantial.
The potentially modest role of SSDI in absorbing individuals after
Great Recession local shocks is consistent with aggregate patterns. The
share of age-1665 Americans on SSDI rose for three decades before de-
celerating after 2010 and declining absolutely in both 2014 and 2015. Ag-
gregate SSDI applications spiked after the Great Recession, as they have
after previous recessions, but Maestas, Mullen, and Strand (2015) use data
through 2012 to estimate that virtually all of the Great Recessioninduced
applications were initially declined. SSDI application is not observed in
this papers data.
VII. Layoffs and Nonemployment Trajectories
Table 5 showed that statistically significant nonemployment effects be-
gan in 2009 and that there were statistically significant effects on UI ben-
efits 200810. A large literature connects layoffs and long-term earnings
losses (Topel 1990; Ruhm 1991; Jacobson et al. 1993; Neal 1995; Kahn
2010; Davis and von Wachter 2011). I therefore provide additional evi-
dence on layoffs and long-term employment losses.
Table 6, column 6, replicates the main specification for the binary out-
come of ever having received UI in 200714a good proxy for everhaving
been laid off in 200714.
30
The column indicates that a 1 percentage point
higher Great Recession local shock induced individuals to be 1.43 per-
centage points more likely to receive UI in 200714, with a t-statistic over
3 and relative to the sample mean of 25.6 percent.
The substantial 200714 layoff effect relative to the 2015 employment
effect suggests that most of the incrementally nonemployed from severely
shocked areas may have been laid off. Column 7 confirms that suggestion.
Analogous to column 2s employed-or-on-SSDI analysis, column 7 repli-
cates the main specification on a new outcome: an indicator for whether
29
That is, the outcome equals maxfEMPLOYED
i2015
, SSDI
i2015
g 2 ð1=8Þo
2006
s51999
EMPLOYED
is
, where SSDI
i2015
equals one if i received SSDI in 2015 and zero otherwise.
30
Kawano and LaLumia (2017) show that UI-tax-data-based unemployment rates are
close in both level and trend to official BLS unemployment rates for 19992011 (correla-
tion: 0.94). Earlier papers typically proxy for layoff by using firm separation during a firms
large downsizing; my measure here is not limited to large downsizings.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2545
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
TABLE 6
Additional Outcomes
A. Disability Insurance Receipt in Main Sample (pp) B. Employment Impacts in Mass Layoffs Sample (pp)
SSDI Receipt
in 2015
(1)
2015 Relative Employment
or SSDI Receipt
(2)
2015 Relative
Employment
(3)
2015 Relative
Employment
(4)
2015 Relative
Employment
(5)
Great Recession local
shock .071 2.265 2.577 2.628 2.605
(.145) (.099) (.126) (.118) (.125)
Main controls X X X X X
Exclude if invalid
industry code XX
Exclude if construction/
manufacturing X
Observations 1,357,974 1,357,974 1,001,543 573,493 396,377
R
2
.12 .09 .11 .17 .15
Outcome mean 6.22 22.28 210.12 210.45 29.85
Absolute outcome mean 6.22 84.06 84.12 83.11 83.20
2546
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
C. Layoffs and Nonemployment in Main Sample
UI Receipt Some-
time 200714
(6)
2015 Relative Employment or
UI Receipt Sometime 200714
(7)
2015 Relative
Employment
(8)
Relative Nonemployment
200714
(9)
2015 Relative
Employment
(10)
201315Relative
Employment
(11)
Great Recession local
shock 1.431 2.019 2.354 .487 2.057 2.285
(.418) (.121) (.099) (.122) (.111) (.101)
UI receipt sometime
200714 22.734
(.142)
Main controls X X X X X X
Employment 200712 X
Observations 1,357,974 1,357,974 1,357,974 1,357,974 1,357,974 1,357,974
R
2
.16 .06 .08 .08 .26 .07
Outcome mean 25.6 22.8 27.2 3.0 27.2 21.2
Absolute outcome mean 25.6 83.6 79.1 3.0 79.1 85.2
Note.The table reports estimates of the specification in table 2, col. 4, with alternative outcomes, samples, and/or controls. Column 1 replicates the main
specification, using the outcome of an indicator for 2015 receipt of Social Security Disability Insurance. Column 2 replicates the main specification, using the
outcome of an indicator for 2015 employment or 2015 SSDI receipt, minus the individuals mean employment 19992006. Column 3 replicates the main spec-
ification, and cols. 4 5 replicate table 3, cols. 1112, in the mass-layoffs sample. Column 6 replicates the main specification, using the outcome of an indicator
for unemployment insurance benefit receipt at some point 200714. Column 7 replicates col. 2 but uses UI receipt in 200714 in place of 2015 SSDI receipt.
Column 8 replicates the main specification, controlling for UI receipt sometime in 200714. Column 9 replicates the main specification, using the outcome of
an indicator for having any year of nonemployment during 200714, minus an indicator for having any year of nonemployment 19992006. Column 10 rep-
licates the main specification while controlling for indicators of employment in each year 200712. Column 11 replicates the main specification, using the
outcome of an indicator for employment in any year 201315, minus the individuals mean employment 19992006. Standard errors (in parentheses) are clus-
tered by 2007 state.
2547
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
the individual was employed in 2015 or received UI at some point in 2007
14, minus the individuals mean employment status in 19992006. The
column 7 estimate is nearly zero and indicates that Great Recession local
shocks had no statistically significant impact on the employed-or-UI out-
come. Hence, most of the incrementally nonemployed from severely
shocked areas had been laid off.
The preceding findings may suggest that the initial residents of severely
shocked areas suffered higher rates of 2015 nonemployment purely be-
cause those residents were laid off from their initial jobs at higher rates.
Two pieces of evidence suggest that that is not the case. First, column 8
replicates the main specification while controlling for the indicator of
ever receiving UI 200714. The Great Recession local-shock coefficient
is barely attenuated, indicating that effects hold within layoff status. It
is easy to see why quantitatively: multiplying the coefficient on UI receipt
(22.73) by the higher rate of UI receipt (1.43) yields the 0.04 percentage
point attenuation in the main estimate. Layoff status is endogenous, but
with homogeneous layoff effects and under the mild monotonicity con-
dition that the marginally laid off in severely shocked areas had weakly
better unobservables (Gibbons and Katz 1991), this result suggests that
layoff effects are not nearly large enough for a 1.43 percentage point higher
layoff rate to explain the 2015 employment effect.
31
More simply, figure 5B replicates figure 4A in the mass-layoffs sample
thereby comparing the employment rates of workers who were displaced
in 20089 mass-layoff events at the same age, in the same initial earnings
bin, and in the same initial industry but in different local areas. If layoff ef-
fects were homogenous across space and severely shocked areas simply ex-
perienced more layoffsand if the incrementally displaced in severely
shocked areas were no worse on unobservables (Gibbons and Katz)then
one would not find a negative 2015 employment effect in the mass-layoffs
sample. Yet figure 5B shows that individuals in the mass-layoffs sample
were 0.577 percentage points less likely to be employed in 2015 for every
1 percentage point higher Great Recession local shock. This result (also
reported in table 6, col. 3) is robust to restricting the sample to mass-layoff
firmswithvalidindustry codes,includingthoseoutsidemanufacturingand
construction (cols. 45). This evidence suggests that this papers 2015
nonemployment effects are not explained purely by higher layoff rates
and parallels work on larger earnings impacts in weak local ( Jacobson
et al. 1993) and aggregate (Davis and von Wachter 2011) labor markets.
31
Under homogenous layoff effects and the monotonicity condition, the UI receipt co-
efficient weakly overstates the layoff effect for workers from severely shocked areas, suggest-
ing that the magnitude of the shock coefficient is a lower bound on the true effect net of
the layoff effect.
2548 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Columns 911 of table 6 return to the main sample to document con-
tinuous nonemployment trajectories. Column 9 replicates the main spec-
ification for the outcome of an indicator for whether the individual was
nonemployed for any year 200714, minus an indicator for whether the
individual was nonemployed for any year 19992006. The estimated co-
efficient implies that Great Recession local shocks resulted in the average
working-age American being 0.487 percentage points more likely to ex-
perience a full year of nonemployment in 200714. Column 10 shows
thatpre-2015 nonemploymentstatisticallyexplains2015nonemployment:
there is no statistically significant correlation between Great Recession lo-
cal shocks and 2015 relative employment once one controls additively for
indicators of employment in each year 200712. Column 11 replicates the
main specification for the outcome of an indicator for whether the indi-
vidual was employed in any year 201315, minus the individuals mean
employment in 19992006. The estimate is 20.285, with a t-statistic of 2.8.
Thus, the point estimates in columns 911 suggest that 2015 employment
impacts typically followed an annual nonemployment impact in 200712
and constituted a third consecutive year of nonemployment impacts.
VIII. Discussion of Mechanisms
The previous section found that one candidate channelhigher layoff
rates with homogenous layoff effectslikely does not explain the papers
results. I close with brief further discussion of six candidate mechanisms:
reduced migration, higher reservation wages on SSDI, lost job-specific
rents, lost firm-specific human capital, general human capital decay, and
persistently low labor demand. Higher reservation wages on SSDI could
explain a sizable portion of the impact. General human capital decay and
persistently low labor demand could explain the full impact.
Reduced migration could in principle explain long-term impacts of
Great Recession local shocks, relative to other local shocks, but does not
appear to do so. First, and despite the possibility of negative-equity mort-
gages impeding homeowner out-migration (Ferreira, Gyourko, and Tracy
2010, 2011), several papers have argued that the Great Recession did not
impede migration (Farber 2012; Schulhofer-Wohl 2012; Valletta 2013;
Şahin et al. 2014). Second, Section II found that 200715 population real-
location was in line with historical responses. Third, figure 6 found that
impact heterogeneity across demographic groups was not systematically
correlated with group migration ratesconsistent with, though not dis-
positive of, a hypothetically higher out-migration rate attenuating little
incidence.
The Great Recession could have induced individuals to supplement their
income with SSDIa costly-to-obtain but typically permanent location-
independent income streamthereby raising their reservation wages and
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2549
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
potentially reducing their employment (Autor and Duggan2003; Maestas,
Mullen, and Strand 2013).
32
Reservation wages are not observed, but the
SSDI channel appears to explain a minority of the results. Column 1 of
table 6 estimated that Great Recession local shocks caused insignificantly
higher 2015 SSDI enrollment, with a point estimate equal to one-fifth of
the main employment effect, while column 2 estimated that one-third of
the incrementally nonemployed were on SSDI in 2015, though with sub-
stantial standard errors. An important caveat is that applying for SSDI
effectively requires nonemployment, so the data are consistent with stra-
tegic labor force exit in order to apply for benefits, even if strategic appli-
cation was unsuccessful through 2015.
Laid-off workers will choose to remain nonemployed after losing a high-
paying rent-sharing job if subsequent wage offers lie below the workers
reservation wage.
33
Lost job-specific rents do not appear to explain the re-
sults. First, the 2015 impact of Great Recession local shocks is large not
only in the main sample but also in the retail chain sampleeven though
retail is a canonical low-rent industry (Krueger and Summers 1988; Katz
and Summers 1989; Murphy and Topel 1990; Gibbons and Katz 1991).
Second, figure 6 showed that the largest impacts were suffered by those with
the lowest initial earnings, where the scope for rents was likely low. Third
and most simply, the same figure shows that the estimated 2015 nonem-
ployment impact appears large for those who had no earnings at all in
2006 and thus certainly had been earning no rents.
A worker losing a job for which she had firm-specific human capital
will choose to remain nonemployed if the workers marginal product
and thus wage at the next-best firm lies below her reservation wage
(Topel 1990; Jacobson et al. 1993). Lost firm-specific human capital at lay-
off does not appear to explain the results, as the quantitative results re-
main essentially intact within displaced individuals (table 6, cols. 58;
fig. 5B). The incrementally laid off in severely shocked areas seem likely
to have had weakly better unobservables, as employers may lay off the un-
observably worst workers first (Gibbons and Katz 1991). Hence, heteroge-
neous layoff effectswith the incrementally laid off being less resilient to
their loss of firm-specific human capitalappear necessary for the firm-
specific human capital channel to explain the results.
The results appear consistent with general human capital decay and
persistently low labor demand. Severe recessions generate relatively long
32
Recipients forfeit their income streams if they return to substantial work.
33
Motivated by the union wage premium (e.g., Lewis 1963; Farber 1986), some empir-
ical commentary has interpreted postlayoff earnings losses as reflecting workers loss of
rents in an initial job that paid above the workers marginal product (e.g., Hall 2011). Pre-
existing contrary evidence includes that postlayoff earnings losses are large and significant
across both high-apparent-rent and low-apparent-rent industries ( Jacobson et al. 1993).
2550 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
nonemployment spells, and general human capital can decay during such
spells (Phelps 1972), leading to persistent nonemployment (Pissarides
1992), such as via job ladders with serially correlated unemployment spells
( Jarosch 2015). For example, workers may fail to keep up with new tech-
nologies or preserve good habits such as punctuality and then may choose
nonparticipation over lower-wage employment ( Juhn, Murphy, and Topel
1991, 2002). Consistent with general human capital decay, columns 1 and
911 of table 6 found that incremental 2015 nonemployment typically
followed a layoff and multiple years of nonemployment in 200714. Gen-
eral human capital decay after a prolonged nonemployment spell is also
consistent with earlier findings of reduced long-term earnings after mass
layoffs in weak local ( Jacobson et al. 1993) and aggregate (Davis and von
Wachter 2011) labor markets.
Alternatively, severely shocked areas may have experienced persistently
low labor demand, and mobility frictions may have resulted in initial resi-
dents bearing the incidence (Kline 2010; Moretti 2011).
34
First, local Great
Recessiondriving processes (e.g., spending contractions or productivity
shocks) could have been persistent, causing wages to fall below reserva-
tion wages (Hall 1992; Kline and Moretti 2014).
35
Second, transitory Great
Recession local shocks may have reduced the opportunity costs for agents
to respond to exogenous nationwide skill-biased or routine-biased techni-
calprogress( JaimovichandSiu[2012],withrecentempiricalsupportfrom
Hershbein and Kahn [2016])accelerating wage declines below reser-
vationwages. Third,transitoryGreat Recession localshocksmayhavemoved
local areas to low-employment equilibria (Diamond 1982; Blanchard and
Summers 1986; Benhabib and Farmer 1994; Christiano and Harrison 1999;
Eggertsson and Krugman 2012; Kaplan and Menzio 2014), where neither
workers norfirms search forjob matcheseventhough both would gain from
trade at the prevailing wage. To the extent that the first and last cases are
reversible, they are consistent with hidden slack among labor force non-
participants. All three cases are consistent with the results, including the
result that most of the incrementally nonemployed had been laid off.
Laid-off workers may be exactly those individuals whose wages fell below
reservation wages, or layoffs may have determined which specific workers
lost out in the new equilibrium without determining how many did.
34
Every decennial census shows that over two-thirds of adults live in their birth state
(Molloy et al. 2011). The Health and Retirement Study shows that half of adults live within
18 miles of their mot hers ( http://www.nytimes.co m/interactive/2 015/12/24 /upshot
/24up-family.html).
35
For example, with only nontradable production, net worth contractions (Mian and
Sufi 2014) could have permanently caused residents to shift to home production (Ben-
habib, Rogerson, and Wright 1991; Aguiar and Hurst 2005), reducing per capita local labor
demand and equilibrium wages below reservation wages.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2551
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
General human capital decay leaves individuals changed (scarred),
while persistently low labor demand leaves local areas changed. Thus,
unique to the persistently-low-labor-demand mechanism, exogenously
moving individuals in 2015 from severely shocked to mildly shocked areas
may increase their employment rate. Future work could therefore distin-
guish between these mechanisms, with strong migration instruments that
generate quasi-experimental variation in individuals 2015 local areas.
36
IX. Conclusion
This paper used local labor markets as a laboratory to test for long-term
employment impacts of the Great Recession. The central finding is that
exposure to a severe local Great Recession caused working-age Americans
to be substantially less likely to be employed at all in 2015, despite recovery
in the local unemployment rate. This finding contrasts with the conven-
tional view that a business cycles employment impacts cease once unem-
ployment recovers. Instead, the Great Recession altered unemployment-
constant employment.
37
The paper highlights five areas for future work. First, the results sug-
gest the importance of allowing for labor force exit in models of macro-
economic fluctuations (Mortensen and Pissarides 1999).
38
Such models
have the potential to show countercyclical policies to be relatively fiscally
inexpensive or even self-financing, to the extent that they persistently in-
crease employment and earnings and thereby tax revenue (DeLong and
Summers 2012). Second, higher layoff rates do not appear to explain the
results, as the impacts hold within a sample of laid-off individuals, point-
ing instead to interactions with area-level economic conditions. Future
analysescouldfurthertestamongmechanisms.Third,newworkcouldinves-
tigate whether previous recessions also depressed long-term employment.
Fourth, naive extrapolation of the papers local-shock-based estimate
to the aggregate would suggest that the Great Recession caused over half
36
In addition, there are other potential mechanisms. For example, workers may have
made costly investments, such as moving in with ones parents (Kaplan 2012) or honing
leisure skills (Aguiar et al. 2017), during nonemployment spells that then induced labor
supply contraction. However, nominal and real hourly wages declined rather than rose
in severely shocked areas (Beraja et al. 2016). Employers may have inferred low unobserved
productivity from long nonemployment spells, though such inference was smallest in se-
verely shocked areas (Kroft, Lange, and Notowidigdo 2013).
37
This conclusion includes the possibility that the recession ended a period of unsus-
tainable unemployment-constant employment, returning the economy to its pre-2000s
trend (Charles et al. 2016).
38
From Mortensen and Pissarides (1999, 1173): Despite a flurry of activity [in search
and matching theory] since [the early 1980s], there are still many important questions that
are unexplored. One such question is the dynamics of worker movement in and out of the
labor force. ...Virtually all search equilibrium models assume an exogenous labor force.
Pissarides (1992) models search intensity that declines with unemployment duration.
2552 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
of the 200715 age-adjusted decline in US working-age employment. Sub-
sequent analysis could determine whether the true aggregate impact was
less or more. Finally, employment impacts through 2015 do not imply
employment impacts forever, and it will be valuable to estimate and ex-
plain subsequent dynamics. For example, the age-2554 US headline em-
ployment rate rose 1.6 percentage points from the beginning of 2016 to
the end of 2017, primarily via labor force entry. This upward 201617 em-
ployment trend could reflect continued cyclical recovery, with there hav-
ing been hidden slack among labor force nonparticipants who subse-
quently reentered the labor force in 201617 (Bell and Blanchflower,
forthcoming). The hidden-slack explanation is consistent with low wage
growth in 201617 and would indicate that the Great Recessionsrecovery
extended anomalously long relative to previous cycles (cf. Fernald et al.
2017). Alternatively, it is possible that the recent upward employment trend
reflects up-skilling, a new positive aggregate shock, or another force.
Appendix
The working-age population (ages 3049 in any given year) has grown older over
time because of the baby boom. To account for this age distribution change, the
extrapolation exercise of Section IV.D uses the following formula to compute
each element in the summation ð1=5Þo
2007
t52003
De
t
:
De
t
5
o
cC
t
l
ct
E EMPLOYED
it
jciðÞ5 c½2
1
8
o
t29
s5t216
E EMPLOYED
is
jciðÞ5 c½

,
where C
t
is the set of birth cohorts ft 2 58, , t 2 39g and the cohort-reweighting
term l
ct
is the population share of cohort c 1 2015 2 t in C
2015
in the March 2016
ASEC. When computing De
t
without cohort reweighting and thus simply
as E½EMPLOYED
it
jcðiÞ C
t
2 ð1=8Þo
t29
s5t216
E½EMPLOYED
is
jcðiÞ C
t
, one obtains
ð1=5Þo
2007
t52003
De
t
524:22 instead of the 24.83 percentage points reported in the
textwhich would reduce the exercises final estimate from 76 percent to 61 per-
cent. ASEC data are limited to the civilian noninstitutional population. The vari-
able EMPLOYED
it
in ASEC is defined as an affirmative answer to either of two
questions asked of respondents in March of t 1 1: Did [person] work at a job
or business at any time during [t]? and Did [person] do any temporary, part-
time, or seasonal work even for a few days during [t]?
References
Aguiar, Mark, Mark Bils, Kerwin Charles, and Erik Hurst. 2017. Leisure Luxuries
and the Labor Supply of Young Men. Working Paper no. 23552 ( June), NBER,
Cambridge, MA.
Aguiar, Mark, and Erik Hurst. 2005. Consumption versus Expenditure. J.P.E.
113 (5): 91948.
Autor, David H., David Dorn, and Gordon H. Hanson. 2013. The China Syn-
drome: Local Labor Market Effects of Import Competition in the United
States. A.E.R. 103 (6): 212168.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2553
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Autor, David H., David Dorn, Gordon H. Hanson, and Jae Song. 2014. Trade
Adjustment: Worker-Level Evidence. Q.J.E. 129 (4): 17991860.
Autor, David H., and Mark G. Duggan. 2003. The Rise in the Disability Rolls and
the Decline in Unemployment. Q.J.E. 118 (1): 157205.
Autor, David H., Lawrence F. Katz, and Melissa S. Kearney. 2008. Trends in US
Wage Inequality: Revising the Revisionists. Rev. Econ. and Statis. 90 (2): 300
23.
Bell, David, and David Blanchflower. Forthcoming. Underemployment in Eu-
rope and the United States. Indus. and Labor Relations Rev. https://www
.dartmouth.edu/~blnchflr/Projects.html.
Benhabib, Jess, and Roger E. A. Farmer. 1994. Indeterminacy and Increasing
Returns. J. Econ. Theory 63 (1): 1941.
Benhabib, Jess, Richard Rogerson, and Randall Wright. 1991. Homework in
Macroeconomics: Household Production and Aggregate Fluctuations. J.P.E.
99 (6): 116687.
Beraja, Martin, Erik Hurst, and Juan Ospina. 2016. The Aggregate Implications
of Regional Business Cycles. Working Paper no. 21956 (February), NBER,
Cambridge, MA.
Black, Dan, Kermit Daniel, and Seth Sanders. 2002. The Impact of Economic
Conditions on Participation in Disability Programs: Evidence from the Coal
Boom and Bust. A.E.R. 92 (1): 2750.
Blanchard, Olivier J., and Lawrence F. Katz. 1992. Regional Evolutions. Brook-
ings Papers Econ. Activity 1992 (1): 161.
Blanchard, Olivier J., and Lawrence H. Summers. 1986. Hysteresis and the Eu-
ropean Unemployment Problem. In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 1986,edited
by Stanley Fischer, 1590. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press (for NBER).
Bowen, William G., and Aldrich T. Finegan. 1969. Unemployment and Labor
Force Participation: Time-Series Relations. In The Economics of Labor Force Par-
ticipation, chap. 16. Princeton, NJ: Princeton Univ. Press.
Card, David, Jörg Heining, and Patrick Kline. 2013.
Workplace Heterogeneity
and the Rise of West German Wage Inequality. Q.J.E. 128 (3): 967 1015.
Charles, Kerwin Kofi, Erik Hurst, and Matthew J. Notowidigdo. 2015. Housing
Booms and Busts, Labor Market Opportunities, and College Attendance.
Working Paper no. 21587 (September), NBER, Cambridge, MA.
———. 2016. The Masking of the Decline in Manufacturing Employment by
the Housing Bubble. J. Econ. Perspectives 30 (2): 179200.
Charles, Kerwin Kofi, Erik Hurst, and Mariel Schwartz. 2018. The Transforma-
tion of Manufacturing and the Decline in U.S. Employment. Working Paper
no. 24468 (March), NBER, Cambridge, MA.
Chetty, Raj, Nathaniel Hendren, Patrick Kline, and Emmanuel Saez. 2014.
Where Is the Land of Opportunity? The Geography of Intergenerational
Mobility in the United States. Q.J.E. 129 (4): 15531623.
Christiano, Lawrence J., and Sharon G. Harrison. 1999. Chaos, Sunspots and
Automatic Stabilizers. J. Monetary Econ. 44 (1): 331.
Clemens, Jeffrey , and Michael Wither. 2014. The Minimum W age and the Great Re-
cession: Evidence of Effects on the Employment and Income Trajectories of Low-
Skilled Workers. Wo rking Paper no. 20724 (December), NBER, Cambridge, MA.
Dao, Mai, Davide Furceri, and Prakash Loungani. 2017. Regional Labor Market
Adjustment in the United States: Trend and Cycle. Rev. Econ. and Statis. 99 (2):
24357.
Davis, Steven J., and Till von Wachter. 2011. Recessions and the Costs of Job
Loss. Brookings Papers Econ. Activity 2011 (2): 155.
2554 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Decressin, Jörg, and Antonio Fatas. 1995. Regional Labor Market Dynamics in
Europe. European Econ. Rev. 39 (9): 162755.
DeLong, J. Bradford, and Lawrence H. Summers. 2012. Fiscal Policy in a De-
pressed Economy. Brookings Papers Econ. Activity 2012 (Spring): 23397.
Diamond, Peter A. 1982. Aggregate Demand Management in Search Equilib-
rium. J.P.E. 90 (5): 88194.
DiNardo, John, Nicole M. Fortin, and Thomas Lemieux. 1996. Labor Market In-
stitutions and the Distribution of Wages, 19731992: A Semiparametric Ap-
proach. Econometrica 64 (5): 1001 44.
Dorn, David. 2009. Essays on Inequality, Spatial Interaction, and the Demand
for Skills. PhD thesis, Univ. St. Gallen.
Eggertsson, Gauti B., and Paul Krugman. 2012. Debt, Deleveraging, and the Li-
quidity Trap: A Fisher-Minsky-Koo Approach. Q. J.E. 127 (3): 14691513.
Farber, Henry S. 1986. The Analysis of Union Behavior. In Handbook of Labor
Economics, vol. 2, edited by Orley C. Ashenfelter and Richard Layard, 1039
89. Amsterdam: North-Holland.
———. 2012. Unemployment in the Great Recession: Did the Housing Market
Crisis Prevent the Unemployed from Moving to Take Jobs? A.E.R. 102 (3):
52025.
Fernald, John G., Robert E. Hall, James H. Stock, and Mark W. Watson. 2017.
The Disappointing Recovery of Output after 2009. Brookings Papers Econ. Ac-
tivity 2017 (Spring): 158.
Ferreira, Fernando, Joseph Gyourko, and Joseph Tracy. 2010. Housing Busts
and Household Mobility. J. Urban Econ. 68 (1): 3445.
———. 2011. Housing Busts and Household Mobility: An Update. Working Pa-
per no. 17405 (September), NBER, Cambridge, MA.
Gibbons, Robert, and Lawrence F. Katz. 1991. Layoffs and Lemons. J. Labor
Econ. 9 (4): 35180.
Hall, Robert. 1992. Comment on Regional Evolutions by Blanchard and Katz.
Brookings Papers Econ. Activity 1992 (1): 6265.
———. 2011. Comment on Recessions and the Costs of Job Loss by Davis and
Von Wachter. Brookings Papers Econ. Activity 2011 (2): 5661.
Hershbein, Brad, and Lisa B. Kahn. 2016. Do Recessions Accelerate Routine-
Biased Technological Change? Working Paper no. 22762 (October), NBER,
Cambridge, MA.
Hilger, Nathaniel G. 2016. Parental Job Loss and Childrens Long-Term Out-
comes: Evidence from 7 Million Fathers Layoffs. American Econ. J.: Appl. Econ.
8 (3): 24783.
Hoynes, Hilary, Douglas L. Miller, and Jessamyn Schaller. 2012. Who Suffers
During Recessions? J. Econ. Perspectives 26 (3): 2747.
Jacobson, Louis S., Robert J. LaLonde, and Daniel G. Sullivan. 1993. Earnings
Losses of Displaced Workers. A.E.R. 83 (4): 685709.
Jaimovich, Nir, and Henry E. Siu. 2012. The Trend Is the Cycle: Job Polarization
and Jobless Recoveries. Working Paper no. 18334 (August), NBER, Cam-
bridge, MA.
Jarosch, Gregor. 2015. Searching for Job Security and the Consequences of Job
Loss. Manuscript, Univ. Chicago.
Juhn, Chinhui, Kevin M. Murphy, and Robert H. Topel. 1991. Why Has the Nat-
ural Rate of Unemployment Increased over Time? Brookings Papers Econ. Activ-
ity 1991 (2): 75142.
———. 2002. Current Unemployment, Historically Contemplated.
Brookings
Papers Econ. Activity 2002 (1): 79116.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2555
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Kahn, Lisa B. 2010. The Long-Term Labor Market Consequences of Graduating
from College in a Bad Economy. Labour Econ. 17 (2): 30316.
Kaplan, Greg. 2012. Moving Back Home: Insurance against Labor Market Risk.
J.P.E. 120 (3): 446512.
Kaplan, Greg, and Guido Menzio. 2014. Shopping Externalities and Self-
Fulfilling Unemployment Fluctuations. J.P.E. 124 (3): 771825.
Katz, Lawrence F., and Kevin M. Murphy. 1992. Changes in Relative Wages,
19631987: Supply and Demand Factors. Q.J.E. 107 (1): 3578.
Katz, Lawrence F., and Lawrence H. Summers. 1989. Can Interindustry Wage
Differentials Justify Strategic Trade Policy? In Trade Policies for International
Competitiveness, edited by Robert C. Feenstra, 85124. Chicago: Univ. Chicago
Press (for NBER).
Kawano, Laura, and Sara LaLumia. 2017. How Income Changes during Unem-
ployment: Evidence from Tax Return Data. J. Human Resources 52 (2): 41856.
Kline, Patrick. 2010. Place Based Policies, Heterogeneity, and Agglomeration.
A.E.R. 100 (2): 38387.
Kline, Patrick, and Enrico Moretti. 2014. Local Economic Development, Ag-
glomeration Economies, and the Big Push: 100 Years of Evidence from the
Tennessee Valley Authority. Q.J.E. 129 (1): 275331.
Kline, Patrick, Neviana Petkova, Heidi Williams, and Owen Zidar. 2018. Who
Profits from Patents? Rent-sharing at Innovative Firms. W orking Paper no. 25245
(November), NBER, Cambridge, MA.
Kroft, Kory, Fabian Lange, and Matthew J. Notowidigdo. 2013. Duration Depen-
dence and Labor Market Conditions: Evidence from a Field Experiment.
Q.J.E. 128 (3): 112367.
Krueger, Alan B., and Lawrence H. Summers. 1988. Efficiency Wages and the
Inter-industry Wage Structure. Econometrica 57 (2): 25993.
Lee, David S. 2009. Training, Wages, and Sample Selection: Estimating Sharp
Bounds on Treatment Effects. Rev. Econ. Studies 76 (3): 10711102.
Lewis, H. Gregg. 1963. Unionism and Relative Wages in the United States: An Empir-
ical Inquiry . Chicago: Univ. Chicago Press.
Maestas, Nicole, Kathleen J. Mullen, and Alexander Strand. 2013. Does Disabil-
ity Insurance Receipt Discourage Work? Using Examiner Assignment to Esti-
mate Causal Effects of SSDI Receipt. A.E.R. 103 (5): 17971829.
———. 2015. Disability Insurance and the Great Recession. A.E.R. 105 (5): 17782.
Mian, Atif, Kamalesh Rao, and Amir Sufi. 2013. Household Balance Sheets,
Consumption, and the Economic Slump. Q. J.E. 128 (4): 16871726.
Mian, Atif, and Amir Sufi. 2009. The Consequences of Mortgage Credit Expan-
sion: Evidence from the US Mortgage Default Crisis. Q.J.E. 124 (4): 144996.
———. 2014. What Explains the 20072009 Drop in Employment? Economet-
rica 82 (6): 21972223.
Mogstad, Magne, Thibaut Lamadon, and Bradley Setzler. 2017. Rent Sharing,
Earnings Dynamics and Transmission of Firm and Market Level Shocks. Man-
uscript, Univ. Chicago.
Molloy, Raven, Christopher L. Smith, and Abigail Wozniak. 2011. Internal Mi-
gration in the United States. J. Econ. Perspectives 25 (3): 17396.
Monras, Joan. 2015. Economic Shocks and Internal Migration: Evidence from
the Great Recession. IZA Discussion Paper no. 8840, Inst. Study Labor, Bonn.
Monte, Ferdinando, Stephen J. Redding, and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg. 2015.
Commuting, Migration, and Local Employment Elasticities. Working Paper
no. 21706 (November), NBER, Cambridge, MA.
2556 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Moretti, Enrico. 2011. Local Labor Markets. In Handbook of Labor Economics,
vol. 4B, edited by David Card and Orley Ashenfelter, 12371313. Amsterdam:
North-Holland.
———. 2013. Real Wage Inequality. American Econ. J. Appl. Econ. 5 (1): 65103.
Mortensen, Dale T., and Christopher A. Pissarides. 1999. Job Reallocation, Em-
ployment Fluctuations and Unemployment. In Handbook of Macroeconomics,
vol. 1B, edited by John B. Taylor and Michael Woodford, 11711228. Amster-
dam: North-Holland.
Mortenson, Jacob A., James Cilke, Michael Udell, and Jonathon Zytnick. 2009.
Attaching the Left Tail: A New Profile of Income for Persons Who Do Not Ap-
pear on Federal Income Tax Returns. Proceedings: Annual Conference on Taxa-
tion and Minutes of the Annual Meeting of the National Tax Association 102:88102.
Mueller, Andreas I., Jesse Rothstein, and Till M. von Wachter. 2015. Unemploy-
ment Insurance and Disability Insurance in the Great Recession. J. Labor Econ.
34 (S1): S445S475.
Murphy, Kevin M., and Robert H. Topel. 1990. Efficiency Wages Reconsidered:
Theory and Evidence. In Advances in the Theory and Measurement of Unemploy-
ment, edited by Yoram Weiss and Gideon Fishelson, 20440. New York: Pal-
grave Macmillan.
Nakamura, Emi, and Jon Steinsson. 2014. Fiscal Stimulus in a Monetary Union:
Evidence from US Regions. A.E.R. 104 (3): 75392.
Neal, Derek. 1995. Industry-Specific Human Capital: Evidence from Displaced
Workers. J. Labor Econ. 13 (4): 65377.
Notowidigdo, Matthew J. 2011. The Incidence of Local Labor Demand Shocks.
Working Paper no. 17167 (November), NBER, Cambridge, MA.
Phelps, Edmund S. 1972. Social Factors in Unemployment Determination. In
Inflation Policy and Unemployment Theory: The Cost-Benefit Approach to Monetary
Planning,5880. New York: Norton.
Pissarides, Christopher A. 1992. Loss of Skill during Unemployment and the
Persistence of Employment Shocks.
Q.J.E. 107 (4): 137191.
Ramey, Valerie A. 2012. Comment on Fiscal Policy in a Depressed Economy.
Brookings Papers Econ. Activity 2012 (1): 27990.
Roback, Jennifer. 1982. Wages, Rents, and the Quality of Life. J.P.E. 90(6): 1257
78.
Rosen, Sherwin. 1979. Wage-Based Indexes of Urban Quality of Life. In Current
Issues in Urban Economics, edited by Peter M. Mieszkowski and Mahlon R.
Straszheim, 74104. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins Univ. Press.
Ruhm, Christopher J. 1991. Are Workers Permanently Scarred by Job Displace-
ments? A.E.R. 81 (1): 31924.
Şahin, Ayşegül, Joseph Song, Giorgio Topa, and Giovanni L. Violante. 2014.
Mismatch Unemployment. A.E.R. 104 (11): 352964.
Schulhofer-Wohl, Sam. 2012. Negative Equity Does Not Reduce Homeowners
Mobility. Fed. Reserve Bank Minneapolis Q. Rev. 35 (1).
Sullivan, Daniel, and Till von Wachter. 2009. Job Displacement and Mortality:
An Analysis Using Administrative Data. Q.J.E. 124 (3): 12651306.
Tolbert, Charles M., and Molly Sizer. 1996. US Commuting Zones and Labor
Market Areas: A 1990 Update. Staff Paper no. AGES-9614, Econ. Res. Service,
Rural Econ. Division, US Dept. Agriculture, Washington, DC.
Topel, Robert. 1990. Specific Capital and Unemployment: Measuring the Costs
and Consequences of Job Loss. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series Public Policy
33:181214.
employment hysteresis from the great recession 2557
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
Vaghul, Kavya, and Ben Zipperer. 2016. Historical State and Sub-state Minimum
Wage Data. Working Paper, Washington Center for Equitable Growth, Wash-
ington, DC. http://equitablegrowth.org/working-papers/historical-state-and
-sub-state-minimum-wage-data/.
Valletta, Robert G. 2013. House Lock and Structural Unemployment. Labour
Econ. 25:8697.
Walker, W. Reed. 2013. The Transitional Costs of Sectoral Reallocation: Evi-
dence from the Clean Air Act and the Workforce. Q.J.E. 128:1787 1835.
Yagan, Danny. 2014. Moving to Opportunity? Migratory Insurance over the
Great Recession. Manuscript, Har vard Univ.
2558 journal of political economy
This content downloaded from 136.152.029.121 on May 28, 2020 09:49:28 AM
All use subject to University of Chicago Press Terms and Conditions (http://www.journals.uchicago.edu/t-and-c).
ONLINE APPENDIX
57
Online Appendix A: Age-Adjusted U.S. Labor Force
Statistics
Online Appendix Figure A.1 uses monthly Current Population Surveys (CPS) to plot un-
adjusted and non-parametrically age-adjusted annual U.S. employment rates (employment-
population ratios), labor force participation rates, and unemployment rates 2007-2015. The
figure’s unadjusted statistics are essentially equal to the official Bureau of Labor Statistics
U.S. labor force statistics. They are constructed as follows using the civilian non-institutional
population, first for the age-16+ population and then separately for the age-25-54 population.
For each age-year and top-coding age at 79, I compute the population-weighted mean across
CPS months of total unemployed, labor force, and population counts. Then to construct the
unadjusted year-t data points, I sum year-t’s unemployed, labor force, and population counts
across ages and use those totals to compute the plotted rates. To construct each age-adjusted
year-t data point, I first reweight year-t’s age-specific counts by the age’s 2007 population share
as in DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux (1996):
ˆ
X
at
=
P
a2007
P
a
P
a2007
P
a
P
at
P
at
X
at
where a denotes age, X denotes an unemployed, labor force, or population (P ) count, and
ˆ
X
at
denotes a reweighted count. The weight
P
a2007
P
a
P
a2007
P
a
P
at
P
at
ranges empirically from 0.63 to 1.25,
depending on whether the age’s population share rose or fell between 2007 and t. I then sum
the reweighted unemployed, labor force, and population counts across ages and use those totals
to compute the plotted age-adjusted rates.
The results displayed in Online Appendix Figure A.1 reveal that the demographic compo-
sitional change of population aging explains a minority (1.6 percentage points) of the overall
employment rate decline (3.6 percentage points) 2007-2015. The figure also shows that popu-
lation aging explains essentially none (0.1 percentage points) of the age-25-54 employment rate
decline (2.6 percentage points).
These results closely match the results of Shimer (2014). Shimer analyzes data through 2014
and finds, like I do, that aging through 2014 explains a minority of the age-16+ employment
rate decline and essentially none of the age-25-54 decline. He also finds that adding other
demographic controls actually deepens the employment rate decline. Eppsteiner, Furman and
Powell (2017) similarly find that either just under or just over half of the 2007-2015 age-16+
employment rate decline is explained by aging, depending on the measurement point in 2015.
To further discuss related literature, the recent and transparent contribution of Krueger
(2017) illuminates the uncertainty in projecting pre-recession trends rather than just control-
ling for demographic compositional changes like population aging. He finds that if one projects
the downward trends in labor force participation during the 1997-2006 period forward to 2017,
one can explain the entire decline in labor force participation through 2017 (though 2015 partici-
pation was still unusually low). However, 1997 was the peak in the U.S. labor force participation
rate, so 1997-2006 participation trends were negative. Krueger reports that if one instead uses
the 1992 -2006 period to estimate pre-recession trends, those trends are mostly flat. Thus the
explanatory power of pre-recession trends depends substantially on the choice of the trend
estimation period.
58
In a simultaneous equation system with many variables, Aaronson, Cajner, Fallick, Galbis-
Reig, Smith and Wascher (2014) find, like Krueger’s 1997-2006-based projection, that most
of the age-adjusted labor force participation rate decline can be explained by projecting pre-
recession trends. However, Hall (2014) suggests that the ACFGSW specification is likely to
be sensitive to reasonable amendments, and at least two projections have proven too aggres-
sive. The earlier similar analysis of Aaronson, Fallick, Figura, Pingle and Wascher (2006)
projected such a large labor force participation rate decline that the actual U.S. participation
rate exceeded their projection after 2014 (ACFGSW Figure 1). Similarly, ACFGSW projected
continued and substantial age-16+ labor force participation declines after the second quarter
of 2014 (their Table 6) while the actual age-16+ participation rate remained constant between
then and the time of this writing (the second quarter of 2017).
All told, this appendix’s analysis finds that the demographic compositional change of popu-
lation aging explains a minority of the overall employment rate decline 2007-2015 and essentially
none of the age-25-54 decline. A review of other work suggests that the explanatory power and
accuracy of pre-recession trends depend substantially on the trend estimation specification.
This paper’s main finding supports the view that 2015 employment rates would have been
higher in lieu of the Great Recession.
Online Appendix B: State-Level Shocks
This online appendix extensively details the autoregressive system of Blanchard and Katz (1992,
BK) used to define state-level Great Recession shocks in Section 2 and elaborates on Figure 2’s
historical comparisons of state-level shock adjustment. The online replication kit contains data
and code that generate the results.
Section 2 estimates state-level adjustment using the updated data used in BK: the annual
Local Area Unemployment Statistics (LAUS) series of employment, population, unemploy-
ment, and labor force participation counts 1976-2015 for 51 states (the 50 states plus the
District of Columbia) produced by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS).
38
Variable defini-
tions are standard and pertain to the age-16-and-over civilian noninstitutional population.
39
BLS compiles LAUS counts from the Current Population Survey (CPS), Current Employment
Statistics (CES) survey, and state administrative unemployment insurance counts—blended to
filter maximal signal from noise using empirical Bayes techniques.
40
Online Appendix Table 3
displays summary statistics.
I employ BK’s canonical empirical model of state labor market outcomes to compute Great
38
LAUS are the official data used to allocate federal transfers across states. The series is limited historically
by the lack of Current Population Survey participation statistics for most states prior to 1976.
39
Age is defined at the time of survey; LAUS figures effectively evenly weight underlying monthly surveys. See
http://www.bls.gov/bls/glossary.htm for full definitions of labor force status. Employment is roughly defined as
working for pay or being temporarily absent from regular work at any point in the reference week. Unemployment
is roughly defined as having had no employment in the reference week but being available for work and having
looked for work in the preceding month. Labor force equals employment plus unemployment.
40
Since LAUS had not yet been produced, BK effectively constructed their own version of LAUS 1976-
1990 using the Geographic Profile of Employment (comprising CPS unemployment and population counts),
employment counts from the CES (comprising formal employment counts), and an ad-hoc CPS-based imputation
for self-employment (population was implied). LAUS-based results on the original BK time series are essentially
identical to BK’s published results.
59
Recession employment shocks for each state. BK imagine a simple spatial equilibrium in which
U.S. states experience one-time random-walk shocks to global demand for their locally produced
and freely traded goods. Those shocks induce endogenous migration responses of workers and
firms via transitory wage changes until state employment rates return to their steady states.
BK aimed to estimate the nature and speed of those responses: do workers move out or do
jobs move in, and over what horizon? To guide their implementation, BK observe empirically
that states differ in long-run employment and population growth rates (e.g. perhaps partly due
to steady improvements in air conditioning that made the Sun Belt steadily more attractive)
and in long-run unemployment rates and participation rates (e.g. due to industrial mix and
retiree population differences) relative to the national aggregate. Thus an attractive model
of the evolution of state labor market outcomes may feature stationary employment growth,
a stationary unemployment rate, and a stationary participation rate (and thus a stationary
employment rate) for each state relative to the corresponding national aggregates.
BK implement such a model. They characterize state adjustment to idiosyncratic state-level
labor demand shocks by estimating the following log-linear autoregressive system in relative
state employment growth, unemployment rates, and participation rates:
g
ln E
st
= α
s10
+ α
11
(2)
g
ln E
s,t1
+ α
12
(2)
g
ln E/L
s,t1
+ α
13
(2)
g
ln L/P
s,t1
+ ε
E
st
g
ln E/L
st
= α
s20
+ α
21
(2)
g
ln E
st
+ α
22
(2)
g
ln E/L
s,t1
+ α
23
(2)
g
ln L/P
s,t1
+ ε
E/L
st
g
ln L/P
st
= α
s30
+ α
31
(2)
g
ln E
st
+ α
32
(2)
g
ln E/L
s,t1
+ α
33
(2)
g
ln L/P
s,t1
+ ε
L/P
st
where E, L, and P denote levels of employment, the labor force, and population in state s in
year t; where denotes a first difference (year t’s value minus year t1’s value); where edenotes
a difference relative to the year’s national aggregate value; and where (2) denotes a vector of
two lags. Thus the first dependent variable (“relative state employment”) is the first difference
of log state employment minus the first difference of log aggregate employment. The second
(“relative state unemployment”) is the log of one minus the state unemployment rate minus the
log of one minus the aggregate unemployment rate. The third (“relative state participation”)
is the log of the state participation rate minus the log of the aggregate participation rate.
Relative state population is the implied residual. Each equation includes a state fixed effect.
I follow BK in weighting states equally rather than by population. Under these assumptions,
the autoregressive coefficients characterize the speed of the average state’s convergence to its
steady state following an unforecasted change in state labor demand: coefficients close to one
imply slow convergence while coefficients close to zero imply fast convergence.
41
41
The BK system embodies four substantive assumptions. First, unforecasted changes in relative state em-
ployment growth ε
E
st
affect contemporaneous relative employment growth, relative unemployment, and relative
participation, but unforecasted changes in relative state unemployment and participation do not effect con-
temporaneous values of the other outcomes. This feature allows the system to be estimated independently via
ordinary least squares. It reflects the assumption that ε
E
st
primarily reflects changes in labor demand rather
than supply—supported in the data by negative values of ε
E
st
typically being followed by state wage declines
rather than increases. Second, each state-year outcome is differenced by the year’s aggregate value, so the
behavior of the system is assumed to be independent of aggregate levels. Third, serial correlation is assumed
to be affine in two lags, which limits the estimation sample to years 1978 and beyond (three and four lags
deliver similar results). Fourth, outcomes are assumed to be stationary, i.e. to converge in the long run to
time-invariant state-specific steady-state values relative to national aggregates. State fixed effects are motivated
by cross-decadal persistence in the outcomes. Formal stationarity tests are underpowered and inconclusive in
60
For each state, I estimate a 2008 and a 2009 employment growth forecast error within the
BK system and refer to their sum as its Great Recession employment shock. Specifically, I
first estimate the BK system coefficients using sample years 1978-2007 (i.e. using years 1976-
2007 with two lags). I then compute each state’s 2008 employment shock
d
ε
E
s,2008
, equal to the
state’s actual relative employment growth
g
ln E
s,2008
minus the relative employment growth
predicted by the state’s actual data through 2007 and the estimated coefficients. For example,
a state that experienced 2008 relative employment growth equal to the system forecast based
on its history through 2007 would have a 2008 shock equal to zero. I similarly compute each
state’s 2009 employment shock
d
ε
E
s,2009
, equal to the state’s actual relative employment growth
g
ln E
s,2009
minus the relative employment growth predicted by the state’s actual data through
2008 and the estimated coefficients. I refer to each state’s vector {
d
ε
E
s,2008
,
d
ε
E
s,2009
} as the state’s
Great Recession employment shocks and to the sum of the vector’s elements as the state’s Great
Recession employment shock.
To understand these shocks empirically, Online Appendix Table 4 lists each state’s Great
Recession employment shock. The standard deviation of state-level shocks over the Great
Recession (2.74) was similar to the standard deviation of state-level shocks over the early-1980s
(1980-1982) recession (2.73) computed similarly (detailed below).
42
Recall that shocks are
effectively defined as 2007-2009 employment level changes relative to the state’s own trend and
the national aggregate. Thus a state can have a negative Great Recession employment shock
either because its employment growth relative to the aggregate became moderately negative
after a history of fast growth (e.g. Arizona) or because employment growth became very
negative after a history of slow growth (e.g. Michigan). Furthermore, just over half of states
naturally experienced a positive Great Recession shock, since shocks are measured relative
to the aggregate. The table displays patterns familiar from popular news accounts and earlier
economics work: Sun Belt states like Arizona, California, and Florida as well as Rust Belt states
like Michigan and Indiana experienced severe Great Recession shocks relative to other states.
As two focal examples, Arizona’s shock equals 2.24% while Texas’s shock equals +1.30%.
Online Appendix Figures A.4A-B plot actual mean responses (solid lines) of state labor
market outcomes to 2007-2009 shocks versus mean historical benchmark responses (dotted
lines) to a 1% shock, following BK’s exposition. Forty-one percent of the average state’s
2007-2009 shock arrived in 2008 while 59% arrived in 2009. To generate historical bench-
mark predicted responses 2008-2015, I therefore feed the BK system the employment resid-
ual vector {
d
ε
E
s,2008
,
d
ε
E
s,2009
} = {−.41, .59} and—for maximum comparability to BK’s original
benchmarks—use coefficients estimated on the original sample years 1978-1990; panel C plots
updated benchmarks.
43
Note that by construction in the BK system, the predicted mean
response to a 1% shock is the negative of the predicted mean response to a +1% shock.
44
short time series (BK). Stationarity here is best motivated by spatial arbitrage priors, no rise in the standard
deviation of outcomes before 2007, and employment rate stationarity after previous recessions (Figure 2A).
42
The standard deviation of shocks is smaller outside aggregate recession years.
43
Strictly speaking, I feed the system the vector {−.41, .59} shrunk multiplicatively by a constant such that
the 2007-2009 change in relative employment is 1% after system feedback effects.
44
Online Appendix Figures A.4A-B correspond closely to BK’s Figure 7, with year 2009 corresponding to year
negative one in BK’s Figure 7. The graphs differ in that the 1% shock in Online Appendix Figures A.4A-B
is spread out over two years instead of one and in that Online Appendix Figures A.4A-B use the official LAUS
series that was released after BK.
61
Panel A’s benchmark predictions depict BK’s core lesson: in response to a 1% change
in a state’s employment relative to the state’s trend and the national aggregate, the 1978-
1990 experience predicts that the state’s population would rapidly fall by 1% relative to the
state’s trend and the national aggregate—such that the state’s employment rate returns to its
steady-state level relative to the aggregate in five years. Colloquially, residents move out and
others stop moving in, rather than jobs moving in or residents remaining nonemployed—and
the adjustment completes quickly. Economically, the adjustment process has been understood
to embody a simple mechanism: a state (e.g. Michigan) experiences a one-time random-walk
contraction in global consumer demand for its locally produced traded good (e.g. cars), which
induces a local labor demand contraction and wage decline, which in turn induces a local labor
supply (population) contraction, which then restores the original local wage and employment
rate.
The mean actual response series equals the estimated mean responses of outcomes across
states within each year. To construct the series, I first compute forecast errors for each year
2008-2015 and for each system outcome, using actual data through 2007 and the coefficients
from the 1978-2007-estimated system.
45
Denote these forecast errors for each variable-state-
year {η
E
st
, η
E/L
st
, η
L/P
st
}. I then regress these forecast errors on 2007-2009 shocks in year-by-year
regressions:
46
η
E
st
=
d
ε
E
s,2008
δ
E
t
+
d
ε
E
s,2009
ζ
E
t
, t
η
E/L
st
=
d
ε
E
s,2008
δ
E/L
t
+
d
ε
E
s,2009
ζ
E/L
t
, t
η
L/P
st
=
d
ε
E
s,2008
δ
L/P
t
+
d
ε
E
s,2009
ζ
L/P
t
, t
This specification is flexible in that it allows for the 2008 and 2009 employment shocks to have
arbitrary additive effects on each subsequent year’s outcomes. The δ and ζ coefficients are mean
actual responses of each outcome in each year to 2007-2009 shocks. I multiply these coefficients
by the 1% 2007-2009 shock {
d
ε
E
s,2008
,
d
ε
E
s,2009
} = {−.41, .59} to obtain the plotted mean actual
response series.
Panel A shows that on a slight lag, mean actual relative population responded identically
to Great Recession shocks as in the historical benchmark—falling by 1% between 2007 and
2014, matching the initial 1% employment decline. However, actual relative employment kept
declining such that employment rates remained diverged across space at nearly their 2009 levels:
for every 1% decline in relative state employment 2007-2009, the relative state employment
rate was 0.45 percentage points lower in 2015 than it was in 2007. This 0.45 percentage-point
employment rate deficit is similar to the 0.48 percentage-point deficit that prevailed in 2009.
Hence, employment rates had far from converged across space by 2015, contrary to history-
based predictions. Panel B separates the employment rate response into the unemployment
rate response and the labor force participation rate response. The graph shows that actual
relative unemployment rates converged across space as in the historical benchmark, while actual
participation rates remained diverged in a stark departure from the historical benchmark.
Online Appendix Figure A.4C shows that updating the historical benchmark to more recent
45
That is, I compute 2008-2015 baseline predictions for how each state’s outcomes would have evolved in
the absence of 2007-2009 shocks based on data through 2007 and the estimated coefficients, and then subtract
predictions those 2008-2015 baseline predictions from actual 2008-2015 values.
46
For 2008, only the 2008 employment shock is included as a regressor.
62
data does not alter the conclusion that post-2007 employment rate convergence was unusually
slow and incomplete. The figure plots the estimated response of the average state’s employment
rate to a 1% employment shock, based on estimating the BK system on three different LAUS
sample ranges: 1978-1990 (the original BK time range, reprinted from panels A-B), 1991-
2007, and 1978-2015.
47
Both the 1978-1990- and 1991-2007-based predictions exhibit five-
year convergence of the state’s employment rate to its steady-state level relative to the the
aggregate. The 1978-2015-based prediction exhibits substantially slower convergence but still
exhibits majority employment rate convergence 2009-2015, in contrast to reality.
48
Hence, the
2007-2015 employment rate divergence is exceptional even relative to fully-updated convergence
predictions.
Finally, Figure 2A (documented in the main text) shows that the slow convergence after
Great Recession shocks was unusual not merely relative to average historical responses but also
relative to the aftermath of the two previous recessions for which a long post-recession time
series is available.
49
Online Appendix Figure A.5 repeats Figure 2A for the labor force participa-
tion rate, unemployment rate, employment growth, and population growth. The participation
and unemployment graphs are constructed exactly as the employment rate graph in Figure
2A. To create the employment growth graph, I first compute each state’s steady state value
for relative employment growth by using the 1978-2007-estimated BK coefficients and solving
the BK system assuming all variables are constant. Then, for each state-year around each re-
cession, I compute actual relative employment growth minus steady state relative employment
growth, cumulate this value beginning in year 5 (year 3 for the early-1980s recession, the
first year available), and proceed to construct the graph exactly as done for employment rates.
The population employment graph is constructed similarly. The graphs show that the unem-
ployment rate and population growth adjustments to Great Recession employment shocks were
broadly similar to those after previous recessions’ shocks. However, the participation rate and
employment growth in severely shocked states exhibited no recovery from 2009 levels relative
to mildly shocked states, in stark contrast to the aftermath of the early-1980s and early-1990s
recessions.
Online Appendix C: Cross-State Employment Gap
This online appendix documents the computation of the 2.01 million cross-state employment
gap statistic reported in Section 2. The employment gap is defined as total 2015 employment
in severely shocked states minus total 2015 employment in mildly shocked states—minus the
difference that would have prevailed if the pre-recession severe-mild employment rate difference
had prevailed in 2015 at 2015 state populations. 2.01 .01635/2 × 250.5 = 2.05, where 1.635
percentage points is the population-weighted equivalent to the 1.736-percentage-point severe-
mild 2015 employment rate deficit plotted in Figure 1B and where 250.5 million was 2015
total population. This formula is not exact because population was not exactly evenly divided
47
See Beyer and Smets (2014) for an earlier re-estimation of the BK system augmented with multi-level factor
modeling to compare U.S. and Europe population responses. See Dao, Furceri and Loungani (2017) for an earlier
re-estimation augmented with instruments to find stronger population responses during aggregate recessions.
48
Slower convergence likely derives from unique divergence after 2007 as well as from alleviated small-sample
stationarity bias in a larger sample (e.g. Hurwicz 1950).
49
The post-2001-recession experience exhibited incomplete convergence before being interrupted by positively
correlated 2007-2009 shocks.
63
between the two state groups, since the unweighted shock median was used to define the groups.
For reference, the exact 2.01 figure is computed as follows.
On average 2002-2007, the population-weighted employment rate in severely shocked states
minus that in mildly shocked states equaled 0.885 percentage points. In 2015, severely
shocked states had an adult civilian noninstitutional population of 142.0 million with a 58.25%
population-weighted employment rate while mildly shocked states had an adult civilian non-
institutional population of 108.5 million with a 60.77% population-weighted employment rate
(note that 58.25 60.77 + 0.885 = 1.635). Then the full-convergence employment rate in
severely shocked states (e
S
) and in mildly shocked states (e
M
) solve:
e
S
e
M
= .00885
142.0 × e
S
+ 108.5 × e
M
= 142.0 × .5825 + 108.5 × .6077
where the first equation imposes full employment rate convergence between severely shocked
and mildly shocked states to the pre-2007 difference and the second equation imposes equal-
ity between the full-convergence aggregate employment level (and rate) and the actual 2015
aggregate employment level (and rate).
The solution is e
S
= 58.96% and e
M
= 59.84%. This implies that 1.005 (= 141.99 ×
(.58959.58251)) million fewer residents of severely shocked states in 2015 were employed than
there would have been had state employment rates returned to their pre-2007 differences at
actual 2015 populations and the actual 2015 aggregate employment rate. Likewise, 1.006 (=
108.52×(.60771.59844)) million more residents of mildly shocked states in 2015 were employed
than there would have been had state employment rates returned to their pre-2007 differences
around the actual 2015 aggregate employment rate. Hence relative to the counterfactual of full
convergence of state employment rates to their pre-2007 differences at actual 2015 populations,
a 2.01-million-person employment gap between severely shocked and mildly shocked states
remained in 2015.
Online Appendix D: Empirical Design in Potential Out-
comes
This online appendix details a binary version of the paper’s empirical design in potential out-
comes. Consider identical local areas c that experienced in 2007-2009 a binary Great Reces-
sion local shock—severe or mild—and no other 2007-2009 shocks. Denote these areas severely
shocked or mildly shocked. SEV ERE
c(i2007)
{0, 1} indicates whether an individual i lived
in 2007 in a severely shocked area. EMP LOY ED
i2015
(1) {0, 1} indicates i’s potential 2015
employment if her 2007 local area was severely shocked, and EMP LOY ED
i2015
(0) {0, 1}
indicates i’s potential 2015 employment if her 2007 local area was mildly shocked. To align
notation simply with the text’s main outcome, assume that all individuals were employed in
every year 1999-2006.
Define the causal effect β
i
of i’s 2007 CZ’s Great Recession local shock on i’s 2015 employ-
ment as the difference in the worker’s potential employment: β
i
EMP LOY ED
i2015
(1)
EMP LOY ED
i2015
(0). Note that β
i
could be zero for some skill types and negative for oth-
ers, for example if only construction or routine workers are affected by a severe local shock
(Jaimovich and Siu 2013, Hershbein and Kahn 2016). But β
i
excludes all nationwide changes
64
that do not vary with local shock severity. The mean E[β
i
] β in a relevant sample of workers
is my causal effect of interest, which I refer to as the causal effect of Great Recession local
shocks.
If workers were randomly assigned in 2007 across local areas, then one could consistently
estimate β as the unconditional observed employment rate difference in longitudinal data
as: E[EMP LOY ED
i2015
|SEV ERE
c(i2007)
= 1] E[EMP LOY ED
i2015
|SEV ERE
c(i2007)
= 0].
Lacking random assignment, I assume empirically that workers were as good as randomly as-
signed conditional on a rich observed vector of pre-2007 characteristics X
i2006
:
EMP LOY ED
i2015
(0), EMP LOY ED
i2015
(1)
SEV ERE
c(i2007)
| X
i2007c(i2007)
Then β can be consistently estimated as the conditional observed employment rate difference
in longitudinal data:
E[EMP LOY ED
i2015
|SEV ERE
c(i2007)
= 1, X
i2007c(i2007)
]
E[EMP LOY ED
i2015
|SEV ERE
c(i2007)
= 0, X
i2007c(i2007)
]
= E[EMP LOY ED
i2015
(1) EMP LOY ED
i2015
(0)].
Two appendix graphs help to justify the interpretation of β presented in Section 3.1. My
interpretation of β is sensible because severely shocked and mildly shocked areas exhibited rela-
tively similar pre-recession trends in the outcomes of interest (shown in Section 4.1) and because
post-2010 unemployment rates converged monotonically across severely shocked and mildly
shocked areas (Figure 2A and Online Appendix Figure A.2A). Moreover, adverse 2010-2015
industry-based shift-share shocks are not positively correlated with adverse Great Recession
local shocks (Online Appendix Figure A.2B).
Online Appendix E: Longitudinal Data
This online appendix provides additional details on the longitudinal linked-employer-employee
data described in Section 3.
First, the universe of business tax returns used is the universe of C-corporate (Form 1120),
S-corporate (Form 1120S), and partnership (Form 1065) tax returns. Businesses that file other
types of tax returns employ a small share of U.S. workers.
Second, Form 1099-MISC data on independent contractor employment are missing in 1999.
Results are very similar when omitting 1999 data.
Third, many retail chain firms are missing from the retail chain sample, both because of
subsidiaries and franchises as described in Section 3 and also because a (likely small) number of
firms outsource their W-2 administration to third-party payroll administration firms that list
their own EINs on W-2s. Nevertheless, the retail chain sample includes very large nationwide
chains.
Fourth and also specific to the retail chain sample, the filing ZIP code on a firm’s busi-
ness income tax return typically but not always refer to the business’s headquarters ZIP code.
Excluding workers at the business’s headquarters is useful because headquarters workers may
perform systematically different tasks than workers at other establishments and thus may pos-
sess different human capital even conditional on baseline earnings. I therefore conservatively
65
exclude firms’ workers living in the CZ with the largest number of the firm’s workers living
there, as well as the CZ with the largest number of the firm’s workers living there as a share of
the total number of workers living there.
Fifth and also specific to the retail chain sample, I consider a firm to have operated in a
CZ in 2006 if it employed at least ten stably located workers who lived in the CZ—defined as
individuals of any age and citizenship with a W-2 from the firm in all years 2005-2007 and the
same residential CZ in all years 2005-2007 based on those W-2s’ payee (residential) ZIP codes.
It is necessary to define CZ operations using more than one year of W-2 data because W-2
payee ZIP code refers to the worker’s ZIP code in January of the year after employment. That
feature implies that almost all firms would appear to have operations in every large CZ if one
were to use only 2006 W-2s to identify CZ operations, since many workers move to large cities.
In Section 3.3, I noted that transition of affected workers to self-employment likely does not
explain the results. An appendix graph helps to justify that conclusion: Current Population
Survey data indicate that changes in state self-employment rates since 2007 were unrelated to
changes in state formal employment rates (Online Appendix Figure A.3).
66
Figure A.1: The Age-Adjusted U.S. Employment Rate Decline
Ages 16+ Ages 25-54
A . Employment Rate D. Employment Rate
58 59 60 61 62 63
Employment rate (%)
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Unadjusted Age-adjusted
75 76 77 78 79 80
Employment rate (%)
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Unadjusted Age-adjusted
B. Labor Force Participation Rate E. Labor Force Participation Rate
63 64 65 66 67
Labor force participation rate (%)
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Unadjusted Age-adjusted
81 81.5 82 82.5 83
Labor force participation rate (%)
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Unadjusted Age-adjusted
C. Unemployment Rate F. Unemployment Rate
5 6 7 8 9 10
Unemployment rate (%)
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Unadjusted Age-adjusted
4 5 6 7 8 9
Unemployment rate (%)
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Unadjusted Age-adjusted
Notes: This figure uses monthly Current Population Surveys (CPS) to plot unadjusted and non-parametrically
age-adjusted annual U.S. employment rates (employment-population ratios), labor force participation rates,
and unemployment rates 2007-2015 for the civilian non-institutional population. The unadjusted statistics
are essentially equal to the official Bureau of Labor Statistics U.S. labor force statistics. The age-adjusted
statistics reweight each age-year’s annual total unemployment, labor force, and population by the age group’s
2007 population share as in DiNardo, Fortin and Lemieux (1996) before summing across ages and computing
the displayed rates. See Online Appendix A for details.
67
Figure A.2: Evidence against Positively Correlated Independent Shocks
A. Unemployment Rates by Shock Severity 2007-2015
4 6 8 10 12 14
Unemployment Rate (%)
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015 2016
Mildly shocked CZs Severly schocked CZs
B. 2010-2015 Shift-Share Shocks vs. Great Recession Local Shocks
15 16 17 18 19
2010-2015 shift-share shock (%)
2 3 4 5 6 7 8
Great Recession local shock (pp)
Notes: Panel A uses LAUS county-level data, aggregated to the CZ-level, to plot monthly mean unemployment
rates 2007-2015 in severely shocked CZs (those with above median Great Recession local shocks) and mildly
shocked CZs (all other CZs). Data points are weighted by CZ population. The post-2001-recession experience
exhibited incomplete convergence before being interrupted by positively correlated 2007-2009 shocks. Panel
B plots 2010-2015 CZ-level shift-share shocks versus Great Recession local shocks. The shift-share shocks are
constructed analogously to Bartik (1991) using County Business Patterns data as follows. Each CZ’s shift-share
shock equals the projected 2010-2015 percentage change in the CZ’s employment based on leave-one-CZ-out
nationwide changes in employment by three-digit NAICS industry categories. That is, a CZ c’s shift-share
shock equals: SHIF T SHARESHOCK
c
=
P
j
E
jc2010
P
j
0
E
j
0
c2010
×
P
c
0
6=c
E
jc
0
2015
P
c
0
6=c
E
jc
0
2010
P
c
0
6=c
E
jc
0
2010
where j denotes a
three-digit industry and E
jct
denotes total employment in industry j in CZ c in year t. The graph bins CZs into
ventiles (five-percentile-point bins) by their Great Recession local shock and then plots the 2007-population-
weighted mean of the 2010-2015 shift share shock within each bin. If CZs that were severely shocked during
the Great Recession had subsequently experienced additional adverse shift-share shocks 2010-2015 related to
the CZs’ industrial compositions, Panel B would have exhibited a negative relationship instead of the displayed
insignificant positive relationship.
68
Figure A.3: Self-Employment vs. Formal Employment Rate Changes
AL
AK
AZ
AR
CA
CO
CT
DE
DC
FL
GA
HI
ID
IL
IN
IA
KS
KY
LA
ME
MD
MA
MI
MN
MS
MO
MT
NE
NV
NH
NJ
NM
NY
NC
ND
OH
OK
OR
PA
RI
SC
SD
TN
TX
UT
VT
VA
WA
WV
WI
WY
-3.5 -3 -2.5 -2 -1.5 -1 -.5 0 .5
2015 self-employment rate minus
2007 self-employment rate (pp)
-6 -4 -2 0 2 4
2015 formal employment rate minus
2007 formal employment rate (pp)
Notes: This graph uses the 2007 and 2015 monthly Current Population Surveys to plot 2007-2015 self-
employment rate changes versus 2007-2015 formal employment rate changes for the adult (16+) civilian non-
institutionalized population. The formal employment rate equals the number of formally employed individuals
(workers for wages or salary in private or government sector) divided by the population. The self-employment
rate equals the number of self-employed individuals (including independent contractors) divided by the popu-
lation. Individuals are classified according to the job in which they worked the most hours. Each year’s rate
equals the monthly rate averaged across the year’s twelve months. Overlaid is the unweighted best-fit line.
69
Figure A.4: State Employment Rate Persistence after 2007-2009 Shocks
A. Employment, Population, and B. Participation, Unemployment, and
Employment Rate after 1% Shock Employment Rates after 1% Shock
-2 -1.5 -1 -.5 0
Deviation from trend and aggregate
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Pred. employment (%) Act. employment (%)
Pred. population (%) Act. population (%)
Pred. employment rate (pp) Act. employment rate (pp)
-.5 -.25 0 .25 .5
Deviation from trend and aggregate
2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 2014 2015
Pred. unemployment rate (pp) Act. unemployment rate (pp)
Pred. participation rate (pp) Act. participation rate (pp)
Pred. employment rate (pp) Act. employment rate (pp)
C. Actual 2007-2014 Employment Rate
-.6 -.5 -.4 -.3 -.2 -.1 0
Deviation from trend and aggregate (pp)
2007
2008
2009
2010
2011
2012
2013
2014
2015
2016
2017
2018
2019
2020
2021
2022
2023
2024
Year relative to shock
Pred. based on 1978-1990 Pred. based on 1991-2007
Pred. based on 1978-2015 Actual 2007-2015
Notes: The dotted lines of panels A-B plot benchmark history-based predictions for state-level responses to
a 1% 2007-2009 state-level employment shock, based on estimating Blanchard-Katz’s (1992) autoregressive
system of state labor market outcomes using LAUS data on the original sample range 1978-1990. The solid
lines plot mean actual state-level responses based on reduced-form regressions of 2008-2014 state-level outcomes
on 2007-2009 state-level shocks. Panel C plots the mean actual employment rate response series from panels
A-B alongside predicted employment rate series based on three estimation time ranges: 1978-1990 (as in panels
A-B), 1991-2007, and 1978-2014. See Online Appendix B for more details.
70
Figure A.5: Great Recession Local Convergence Compared to History: Extended
A. Labor Force Participation Rate B. Unemployment Rate
-2 -1.5 -1 -.5 0 .5
Participation rate difference between severely
shocked and mildly shocked states (pp)
-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Year relative to recession
1980-1982 recession
1990-1991 recession
2007-2009 recession
-.5 0 .5 1 1.5 2 2.5
Unemployment rate difference between severely
shocked and mildly shocked states (pp)
-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Year relative to recession
1980-1982 recession
1990-1991 recession
2007-2009 recession
C. Employment Growth D. Population Growth
-8 -6 -4 -2 0
Employment growth: severely shocked states
minus mildly shocked states (log pts)
-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Year relative to recession
1980-1982 recession
1990-1991 recession
2007-2009 recession
-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1
Population growth: severely shocked states
minus mildly shocked states (log pts)
-5 -4 -3 -2 -1 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
Year relative to recession
1980-1982 recession
1990-1991 recession
2007-2009 recession
Notes: Panels A-B replicate Figure 2A for the labor force participation rate and unemployment rate. Panels
C-D display analogous graphs for employment growth and population growth. These latter panels require that
each state’s estimated steady state annual growth rate is subtracted from its actual annual growth, before
constructing the graphs exactly as in Panels A-B. See Online Appendix B and the notes to Figure 2.
71
Outcome:
Individual-level 2015 relative
employment (from tax data)
CZ-level estimated employment
effect (from tax data)
CZ-level 2015 relative employment
(from BLS LAUS and Census)
(pp) (pp) (pp)
(1) (2) (3)
Great Recession local shock
-0.393 -0.381 -0.490
(0.097) (0.100) (0.115)
Main controls
X
Main sample (individual-level)
X
Published sample (CZ-level)
X X
N
1,357,974 591 591
R
2
0.07 0.10 0.09
ONLINE APPENDIX TABLE 1
Approximating the Main Result Using Published Data
Notes – This table shows that the paper's main estimate of the 2015 employment impact of Great Recession local shocks—which uses the main
sample's non-public individual-level data—can be well-approximated in CZ-level data published alongside this paper. Column 1 reprints the main
specification and estimate from Table 2 column 4. Columns 2-3 report coefficients from univariate CZ-level regressions weighted by the CZ's 2007
population as reported in Census's Annual County Resident Population Estimates of the total adult (16+) population, aggregated to the CZ level. The
column 2 outcome equals the estiamated coefficients on a vector of CZ fixed effects from estimating the main specification with Great Recession local
shock variable replaced by a vector of CZ fixed effects. Online Appendix Table 2 lists these estimated coefficients for the hundred largest CZs. The
column 3 outcome variable equals the CZ's 2015 adult employment rate minus the CZ's mean 1999-2007 employment rate, based on Census data and
Bureau of Labor Statistics Local Area Unemployment Statistics data: LAUS county-level 16+ civilian non-institutional employment aggregated to the CZ
level, divided by Census's CZ population estimate. Column 3 is restricted to the CZs available for column 2. Standard errors are clustered in column 1
by the individual's 2007 state and in columns 2-3 by the CZ's state. See the paper's Online Data Codebook and Online Data Tables for additional
details and published variables on the author's website.
Outcome (relative or
absolute):
Employed
Migrated
outside 2000
CZ
Employed in
2000 CZ
Employed
outside 2000
CZ
Earnings
Earnings in
2000 CZ
Earnings
outside 2000
CZ
UI income SSDI income
(pp) (pp) (pp) (pp) ($) ($) ($) ($) ($)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8) (9)
Effect in 2000
-0.036 0.000 -0.036 0.000 72 72 0 0.6 0.4
(0.083) (0.083) (66) (66) (6.2) (3.9)
Effect in 2001
-0.094 -0.036 -0.093 -0.001 -74 -67 -7 10.6 0.3
(0.045) (0.166) (0.044) (0.003) (46) (42) (6) (9.2) (4.6)
Effect in 2002
-0.068 -0.047 -0.060 -0.008 -56 -47 -9 9.7 0.7
(0.018) (0.280) (0.017) (0.004) (26) (23) (5) (15.4) (5.4)
Effect in 2003
-0.044 -0.005 -0.036 -0.008 -26 -17 -10 10.2 0.6
(0.029) (0.361) (0.031) (0.007) (21) (20) (6) (15.9) (5.8)
Effect in 2004
0.031 0.077 0.030 0.001 1 6 -5 11.0 0.3
(0.039) (0.437) (0.036) (0.009) (36) (30) (12) (11.9) (6.6)
Effect in 2005
0.083 0.151 0.070 0.013 40 42 -1 6.8 -0.1
(0.061) (0.526) (0.053) (0.010) (66) (57) (22) (11.5) (7.3)
Effect in 2006
0.228 0.252 0.189 0.039 -15 1 -16 9.1 0.4
(0.135) (0.612) (0.116) (0.020) (118) (94) (36) (13.1) (9.1)
ONLINE APPENDIX TABLE 2
Adjustment Margins Pre-Trends
Notes – This table replicates Table 5 for years 2000-2006 and where each individual's Great Recession local shock equals the 2007-2009 percentage-point unemployment
rate change in the individual's 2000 CZ. See the notes to Table 5 for details.
Mean Standard Deviation
(1) (2)
Employment rate (%)
1978-2015 62.3 4.6
2007 64.1 3.9
2009 60.7 4.5
2015 60.4 4.4
Unemployment rate (%)
1978-2015 6.1 2.1
2007 4.4 1.0
2009 8.5 2.0
2015 5.0 1.1
Labor force participation rate (%)
1978-2015 66.3 4.1
2007 67.0 3.8
2009 66.3 4.0
2015 63.6 4.1
Number of states
Number of years
Number of observations (state-years)
Notes – This table lists summary statistics of the Bureau of Labor Statistics's Local Area
Unemployment Statistics (LAUS) state-year labor force statistics 1978-2015. The LAUS data cover
the adult (16+) civilian non-institutional population of the fifty states and the District of Columbia.
The employment rate is the ratio of employment to population. The unemployment rate is the ratio
of unemployed to labor force. The labor force participation rate is the ratio of labor force to
population.
ONLINE APPENDIX TABLE 3
Summary Statistics: State-Level Data
1,938
51
38
Great
Recession
Employment
Shock Rank
State
Great
Recession
Employment
Shock
Change in
Employment
Rate
2007-2015
Great
Recession
Employment
Shock Rank
State
Great
Recession
Employment
Shock
Change in
Employment
Rate
2007-2015
(pp) (pp) (pp) (pp)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
1 Nevada -6.46 -6.94 27 Washington 1.13 -5.21
2 Alabama -3.42 -5.54 28 New Hampshire 1.13 -2.03
3 Michigan -3.36 -2.74 29 Missouri 1.24 -1.42
4 Georgia -3.19 -7.09 30 Arkansas 1.26 -4.79
5 Delaware -3.14 -4.65 31 Texas 1.30 -2.06
6 Mississippi -3.04 -4.21 32 Virginia 1.56 -4.87
7 Utah -2.53 -4.31 33 Maryland 1.92 -2.79
8 Florida -2.40 -5.45 34 Louisiana 1.99 -2.41
9 South Carolina -2.35 -3.59 35 Massachusetts 2.06 -1.64
10 Arizona -2.24 -4.82 36 Alaska 2.26 -3.67
11 Idaho -2.20 -4.53 37 Minnesota 2.33 -2.24
12 North Carolina -2.15 -4.79 38 New Jersey 2.37 -3.21
13 Tennessee -1.56 -5.18 39 West Virginia 2.58 -4.18
14 Indiana -1.52 -2.45 40 Pennsylvania 2.68 -2.15
15 Hawaii -1.33 -4.27 41 New York 2.79 -2.28
16 Oregon -1.29 -4.33 42 Oklahoma 3.25 -1.90
17 California -0.63 -3.74 43 Connecticut 3.33 -3.33
18 New Mexico -0.57 -6.80 44 South Dakota 3.56 -3.98
19 Illinois -0.33 -4.02 45 Wyoming 3.85 -4.30
20 Ohio 0.05 -4.19 46 Kansas 4.35 -2.98
21 Montana 0.46 -3.45 47 Vermont 4.38 -2.93
22 Colorado 0.73 -5.15 48 Nebraska 4.77 -2.99
23 Wisconsin 0.75 -2.48 49 Iowa 5.00 -2.03
24 Rhode Island 0.81 -3.98 50 District of Columbia 5.44 0.94
25 Kentucky 0.90 -4.60 51 North Dakota 5.75 -2.48
26 Maine 1.09 -3.39
ONLINE APPENDIX TABLE 4
State-Level Great Recession Employment Shocks and 2007-2015 Employment Rate Changes
Notes – This table lists the Great Recession state-level employment shocks and 2007-2015 percentage-point changes in state-level employment
rates that underlie the severe-vs-mild-shock grouping of Figure 1B. See the notes to those figures and Online Appendix B for details. Severely
shocked states are listed on the left; mildly shocked states are listed on the right.
Outcome relative to pre-2007 mean:
(pp) (pp) (pp) (pp) (pp) (pp) (pp) (pp)
(1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (6) (7) (8)
Great Recession local shock -0.393 -0.375 -0.393 -0.393 -0.393 -0.393 -0.369 -0.366
(0.097) (0.107) (0.082) (0.100) (0.092) (0.094) (0.097) (0.097)
Main controls X X X X X X X X
Locally deflating earnings in fixed effects X
CZ has valid Hispanic share 2009-2015 X X
Change in Hispanic share 2009-2015 X
Clustering on 2007 state and 2006 industry X
Clustering on 2007 state and age X
Clustering on 2007 state and 2006 earnings bin X
Clustering on 2007 state and 2006-age- X
earnings-industry
N 1,357,974 1,357,974 1,357,974 1,357,974 1,357,974 1,357,974 1,271,391 1,271,391
R
2
0.07 0.08 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.06 0.08 0.08
Notes – Column 1 reprints the paper's main estimate from Table 2 column 4. Column 2 uses locally deflated 2006 earnings when constructing the 2006-age-
earnings-industry fixed effects. Columns 3-4 two-way cluster on the listed variables. Column 7 repeats column 1 for the individuals whose 2007 CZs have a non-
missing Hispanic share in 2009 and 2015 in the American Community Survey. Column 8 controls for the individual's 2007 CZ's 2015 Hispanic share minus that
CZ's 2009 Hispanic share.
Employed in 2015
LETTER TABLE 1
Specifications for Referee Responses
Effect Rank CZ Name
Estimated
Employment
Effect
Effect Rank CZ Name
Estimated
Employment
Effect
(pp) (pp)
(1) (2) (3) (5) (6) (7)
1
Fayetteville, NC -4.11 51 Cincinnati, OH 0.14
2 Albuquerque, NM -3.95 52 Portland, OR 0.15
3 Deltona, FL -2.97 53 Grand Rapids, MI 0.19
4 Pensacola, FL -2.88 54 Charlotte, NC 0.26
5 Bakersfield, CA -2.46 55 San Jose, CA 0.28
6 Jacksonville, FL -2.45 56 Columbus, OH 0.28
7 Birmingham, AL -2.43 57 Harrisburg, PA 0.28
8 Little Rock, AR -2.30 58 Los Angeles, CA 0.30
9 Toledo, OH -2.26 59 Rockford, IL 0.30
10 Lakeland, FL -2.13 60 Atlanta, GA 0.32
11 Greenville, SC -2.12 61 Allentown, PA 0.34
12 Sarasota, FL -1.92 62 Canton, OH 0.37
13 Las Vegas, NV -1.86 63 Erie, PA 0.40
14 Baton Rouge, LA -1.83 64 Indianapolis, IN 0.41
15 Palm Bay, FL -1.77 65 Albany, NY 0.41
16 Eugene, OR -1.62 66 Louisville, KY 0.45
17 Tampa, FL -1.39 67 Newark, NJ 0.51
18 Knoxville, TN -1.37 68 Toms River, NJ 0.51
19 Columbia, SC -1.26 69 Cleveland, OH 0.52
20 Modesto, CA -1.24 70 Santa Barbara, CA 0.52
21 Tulsa, OK -1.23 71 Raleigh, NC 0.53
22 Fresno, CA -1.23 72 Bridgeport, CT 0.55
23 Tucson, AZ -1.04 73 San Diego, CA 0.58
24 Charleston, SC -1.02 74 Washington, DC 0.58
25 New Orleans, LA -0.98 75 Buffalo, NY 0.59
26
Sacramento, CA -0.93
76
Kansas City, MO 0.61
27
Phoenix, AZ -0.90
77
San Antonio, TX 0.66
28
Nashville, TN -0.89
78
Poughkeepsie, NY 0.67
29
San Francisco, CA -0.80
79
South Bend, IN 0.75
30
Oklahoma City, OK -0.80
80
Syracuse, NY 0.82
31
St. Louis, MO -0.80
81
Scranton, PA 0.83
32
Virginia Beach, VA -0.78
82
New York, NY 0.91
33
Memphis, TN -0.74
83
Austin, TX 1.12
34
Dayton, OH -0.67
84
Fort Worth, TX 1.13
35
Greensboro, NC -0.64
85
Chicago, IL 1.28
36
Detroit, MI -0.59
86
Milwaukee, WI 1.29
37
Richmond, VA -0.47
87
Pittsburgh, PA 1.42
38
Portland, ME -0.41
88
Manchester, NH 1.43
39
Providence, RI -0.26
89
Madison, WI 1.46
40
Youngstown, OH -0.22
90
Houston, TX 1.55
41
Spokane, WA -0.14
91
Boston, MA 1.70
42
Seattle, WA -0.10
92
Dallas, TX 1.78
43
Gary, IN 0.02
93
Des Moines, IA 1.79
44
Cape Coral, FL 0.02
94
Reading, PA 1.93
45
Orlando, FL 0.04
95
Miami, FL 1.94
46
Baltimore, MD 0.04
96
Minneapolis, MN 2.14
47
Springfield, MA 0.06
97
El Paso, TX 2.58
48
Port St. Lucie, FL 0.09
98
Salt Lake City, UT 2.61
49
Denver, CO 0.10
99
Omaha, NE 2.98
50
Philadelphia, PA 0.13
100
Brownsville, TX 5.47
ONLINE APPENDIX TABLE 2
Estimated Employment Effects for the 100 Largest Commuting Zones
Notes - This table lists estimated effects of living in 2007 in each of the hundred largest CZs on 2015 employment, drawn
from the complete data published online. The paper's main specification (Table 2 column 4) regresses 2015 relative
employment (2015 employment minus mean 1999-2006 employment) on Great Recession local shocks and 2006-age-
earnings-industry fixed effects. To generate this table, I repeat the main specification except that I replace the Great
Recession local shock variable with a vector of CZ fixed effects. I then de-mean the 2007-population-weighted fixed
effects and list the fixed effects of the hundred largest CZ's by 2007 population. 2007 population is drawn from Census's
Annual County Resident Population Estimates of the total 16+ population aggregated to the CZ level. See Online Data
Table 1 on the author's website for the full list of CZ-level effects and other CZ-level statistics. Online Appendix Table 1
column 2 shows that the published CZ-level data can be used to approximate the paper's main individual-level regression
result.