NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
DISTRIBUTIONAL NATIONAL ACCOUNTS:
METHODS AND ESTIMATES FOR THE UNITED STATES
Thomas Piketty
Emmanuel Saez
Gabriel Zucman
Working Paper 22945
http://www.nber.org/papers/w22945
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
December 2016
We thank Tony Atkinson, Oded Galor, David Johnson, Arthur Kennickell, Jean-Laurent
Rosenthal, John Sabelhaus, David Splinter, and numerous seminar and conference participants
for helpful discussions and comments. Antoine Arnoud, Kaveh Danesh, Sam Karlin, Juliana
Londono-Velez, Carl McPherson provided outstanding research assistance. We acknowledge
financial support from the Center for Equitable Growth at UC Berkeley, the Institute for New
Economic Thinking, the Laura and John Arnold foundation, NSF grant SES-1559014, the Russell
Sage foundation, the Sandler foundation, and the European Research Council under the European
Union's Seventh Framework Programme, ERC Grant Agreement No. 340831. The views
expressed herein are those of the authors and do not necessarily reflect the views of the National
Bureau of Economic Research.
NBER working papers are circulated for discussion and comment purposes. They have not been
peer-reviewed or been subject to the review by the NBER Board of Directors that accompanies
official NBER publications.
© 2016 by Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez, and Gabriel Zucman. All rights reserved. Short
sections of text, not to exceed two paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission
provided that full credit, including © notice, is given to the source.
Distributional National Accounts: Methods and Estimates for the United States
Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez, and Gabriel Zucman
NBER Working Paper No. 22945
December 2016
JEL No. E01,H2,H5,J3
ABSTRACT
This paper combines tax, survey, and national accounts data to estimate the distribution of
national income in the United States since 1913. Our distributional national accounts capture
100% of national income, allowing us to compute growth rates for each quantile of the income
distribution consistent with macroeconomic growth. We estimate the distribution of both pre-tax
and post-tax income, making it possible to provide a comprehensive view of how government
redistribution affects inequality. Average pre-tax national income per adult has increased 60%
since 1980, but we find that it has stagnated for the bottom 50% of the distribution at about
$16,000 a year. The pre-tax income of the middle class—adults between the median and the 90th
percentile—has grown 40% since 1980, faster than what tax and survey data suggest, due in
particular to the rise of tax-exempt fringe benefits. Income has boomed at the top: in 1980, top
1% adults earned on average 27 times more than bottom 50% adults, while they earn 81 times
more today. The upsurge of top incomes was first a labor income phenomenon but has mostly
been a capital income phenomenon since 2000. The government has offset only a small fraction
of the increase in inequality. The reduction of the gender gap in earnings has mitigated the
increase in inequality among adults. The share of women, however, falls steeply as one moves up
the labor income distribution, and is only 11% in the top 0.1% today.
Thomas Piketty
Paris School of Economics
48 Boulevard Jourdan
75014 Paris, France
Emmanuel Saez
Department of Economics
University of California, Berkeley
530 Evans Hall #3880
Berkeley, CA 94720
and NBER
Gabriel Zucman
Department of Economics
University of California, Berkeley
530 Evans Hall, #3880
Berkeley, CA 94720
and NBER
1 Introducti on
Income inequality has i n cr ea sed in many developed countries over the last se veral decades.
This trend has attrac te d considerable interest among academics, polic y- m akers, and the gen er a l
public. In recent years, followin g up on Kuznets’ (1953) pioneering attempt, a number of authors
have used administrative tax records to construct long-run series of top income shares (Alvaredo
et al., 2011-2016). Yet despite this endeavor, we still face three importa nt l i m i t at i o n s when
measuring income inequality. First and most importa nt, there is a larg e gap between nation al
accounts— wh i ch focus on macro totals and growth—and inequality studies—which focus on
distributions using survey and t a x data, usu al l y without trying to be ful l y consistent with
macro totals. This gap makes it hard to address questions such as: What fraction of economic
growth accrues to the bo t t om 50%, the middle 40%, and the top 10% of the distribution? How
much of the rise in income inequality owes to changes in the share of labo r and capital in national
income, and how much to changes in the dispersion of labor earni n gs , capital ownership, and
returns to capital? Second, about a third of U.S. national income is redistributed through taxes,
transfers, and public good spending . Yet we do not have a good measure of how the distribution
of pre-ta x income differs from the distribution of po st -t a x income, mak i n g it hard to assess how
government redi st ri b u t i o n affects inequality. Th i rd , existing income inequality st a t i st i cs use the
tax unit or the household as unit of observation, ad d i n g up t h e i n co m e of men an d women. As a
result, we do not have a clea r vi ew of how long-run trends in income concentration are shaped by
the major changes in women labor force participation—and gender inequality general l y— th a t
have occurred over the last century.
This paper attempts to compute ineq u a l i ty statistics for the United States that overcome the
limits of existing series by creating distributional national accounts. We combine tax, survey,
and n a t i on a l accounts data to bui l d new series on the distribution of national inc om e since
1913. In contrast to previo u s attempts that capture less than 60% of US n at i on a l income—
such as Census bureau estimates (US Census Bureau 2016) and top income shares (Piketty
and Saez, 2003)—our estimates capture 100% of the nati o n al income recorded in the natio n a l
accounts. This enables us to provide decomposit i o n s of growth by income groups consistent
with macroeconomic growth. We co m p u t e the distribution of both pre-tax and post -t ax income.
Post-tax series deduct all tax es and add back all transfers and publi c spending, so that both
pre-tax and post-tax in co m es add up to national incom e. This al l ows us to provide the first
comprehensive view of how government redistribution affects inequality. Our benchmark series
uses the adult individual as the unit of obser vation and splits in co me eq u al l y a m o n g spouses.
1
We also rep o r t series in which each spous e is assigned her or his own labor income, enabling us
to study how long-run changes in gender inequality shape the distribution of i n co m e.
Distributional nation al accounts provide information on the dynamic of income acro ss the
entire spectrum—from the bottom decile to the top 0. 00 1% — th a t , we believe, is more accurate
than existing inequality data. Our estimates capture employee fringe benefits, a growin g source
of income for the middle-class that is overlooked by both Census bureau estimates and tax
data. They capture all capital income, which is large—about 30% of total national income—
and concentrated, yet is very imperfectly covered by surveys—due to small sample and top
coding issues—and by tax data—as a large fraction of capit a l income g oes to pension funds and
is re ta i n ed in corporations. They make it possible to produce long-run inequality statistics that
control for socio-demographic changes—such as the rise in the fraction of retired individuals
and the decline in household size—contrary to the currently available tax-based series.
Methodologically, our contribution is to construct mic ro -fi l e s of pre-tax and post-tax income
consistent with macro aggregates. These micro-files contain all the variables of the national
accounts and synthetic individ u a l observations that we obtain by statistical l y match i n g tax
and survey data and making explicit assumptions about the distribution of income categories
for whi ch there is no directly available source of i n fo r m at i o n . By construction, the t o t al s in
these micro-files add up to the national accounts totals, while the distributions are consistent
with those seen in tax and survey d a t a. These files can be used to compute a wide array
of distributional statistics—labor and capi ta l i n co m e earne d , taxes paid, transfer s rece i ved,
wealth owned, etc. —by age groups, gender, and marital status. Our objective, in the years
ahead, is to c on st r u ct similar micro-files in as many countries as possible in order to better
compare inequality across countries.
1
Just like we u se GDP or national income to compare the
macroeconomic performances of countries today, so coul d distributional national accounts be
used to compare ineq u a l i ty across countries tomorrow.
We stress at the outset that there are numerous data issues involved in distributing national
income, discussed in the text and the online appendix.
2
First, we take the national accou nts
as a given sta rti n g point, although we a r e well aware that the national accounts themsel ves are
imperfect (e. g. , Zucman 2013). They are, however, the most reasona b l e starting point, because
they aggregate all the available information from surveys, tax data, corporate income state-
1
All updated files and results will be made available on-line on the World Wealth an d Income Database
(WID.world) website: http://www.wid.world/. All the US results and data are also posted at http:
//gabriel-zucman.eu/usdina/.
2
The online appendix is available at http://gabriel-zucman.eu/files/PSZ2016DataAppendix.pdf.
2
ments, and balance sheets, etc., in an standardized, internationally-agr eed -u pon and regularly
improved upon accounting framework. Secon d , impu t i n g all national income, taxes, transfers,
and public goods spending requires making assumptions on a number of complex issues, such as
the economic incidence of taxes and who benefits from government spending. Our goal is not to
provid e definiti ve answers to these questions, but rather to be comprehensive, consist ent, and
explicit about what assumptions we are making and why. We view our paper as attempting to
construct prototyp e distributional national accounts, a pr ot o type that could be improved upon
as more dat a become available, new knowledge emerges on who pays t ax es and benefits from
government spend i n g , an d refined estimat i o n techniques are developed—just as today’s national
accounts are regularly improved.
The analysis of our US distributional national acco u nts yield s a number of striking findings.
First, our data show a sharp diverge n ce in the growth experienced by the bottom 50% versus
the rest of th e economy. The average pre-tax income of the bottom 50% of adults has stagnated
since 1980 at a bout $16,000 per adult (i n constant 2014 dollars, using the national income
deflator), while average national income per adult has grown by 60% to $64,500 in 2014. As a
result, the bottom 50% income share has coll ap se d from about 20% in 1980 to 12% in 2014. In
the meantime, the average pre-tax income of top 1% adu l ts rose from $420,000 to about $1.3
million, and their income share increa sed from about 12% in the early 1980s to 20% in 2014.
The two gr o u p s have essential l y switched their income shares, with 8 points of national income
transferred from the bottom 50 % to the top 1%. The top 1% income shar e is now almost twice
as lar g e as the bottom 50% s h are, a group th a t is by definition 50 t i m es more numerous. In
1980, top 1% adults earned on average 27 times more than bottom 50% adults before tax while
today they earn 81 times more.
Second, gover n m ent redistribut i on has o ffse t only a small fraction of the increase in pre-tax
inequality. Even after taxes and transfe rs , there has been close to zero growth for working-age
adults in the bottom 50% of the distribution since 1980. The aggregate flow of individualized
government transfers ha s increased, but these transfers are largely targeted to the elderly and
the middle-class (individuals above the me d i an and below the 90th percentile). Transfers that
go to the bottom 50% have not been large enough to lift income significantly. Given the massive
changes in the pre-tax di st r i b u t i on of natio n a l income si n ce 1980, there are clear limits to what
redistributive policies can achieve. In light of the collapse of bottom 50% primary incomes,
we feel th a t policy discussions should focus on how to equalize the distribution of p r i m a ry
assets, including human capital, financial capital, and bargaining power, rather than merely
3
ex-post redistribution. Poli ci es that could raise bottom 50% pre-tax incomes include improved
education and access to skills, which may r eq u i re major changes in the system of education
finance and admission; reforms of l a bo r m a rket institutions, in cl u d i n g minimu m wage, corporate
governance, and wo r ker co-determination; and steeply progressive taxation, which can affect pay
determination and pre-tax distr i b u t i on , particularly at the top end (see, e.g., Piketty, Saez and
Stantcheva 2014, and Piketty 2014).
Third, we find that the upsurge of top incomes has mostly been a capital- d r i ven phenomenon
since the lat e 1990s. There is a widespread view that rising income inequ al i ty most ly owes to
booming wages at the top end, i.e., a rise of the “wor k i n g rich.” Our results confirm that this
view is correct from the 1970s to the 1990s. But in contra st to earlier decades, the increase in
income concentration over the last fifteen years owes to a boom in the in com e from equity and
bonds at the top. The working rich are either turning into or bei n g replaced by rent i er s. Top
earners became younger in the 1980s and 1990s but have been growing older since then.
Fourth, the r ed u c ti o n in the gender gap has mitigated the increase in inequality among
adults since the la te 1960s, but the United States is still characterized by a spectacular glass
ceiling. When we allocate labor incomes to indivi d u a l earners (instead of splitting it equally
within couples , as we do in our benchmark series), the rise in inequality is less drama tic , than k s
to the rise of female labor market participation. Men aged 20-64 earned on average 3.7 times
more labor income than women aged 20-64 i n the early 1960s, while they earn 1.7 times more
today. Until the early 1980s, the top 10%, top 1%, and top 0.1% of the labor income distribution
were less than 10% women. Since then, this share has increased, but the increase is smaller the
higher one moves up in the distrib u t i on . As of 2014, women make only about 16% of the top
1% lab o r income earners, and 11% of the top 0.1%.
The paper is organized as fol l ows. Section 2 relates our work to the existing literature.
Section 3 lays out our methodology. In Section 4, we present our results on the distribution
of pre-tax and post-tax national income, and we provide decompositions of growth by income
groups consistent with macroeconomic growth. Sectio n 5 analyze s the role of changes in gender
inequality, factor shares, and taxes and transfers for the dynamic of US i n co m e inequality. S ec-
tion 6 compa r es and reconciles our r esu l t s with previous estimates of US income con centration.
We conclude in Secti on 7.
4
2 Previous Attempts at Introducing Distributional Mea-
sures in the National Accounts
There is a long tradition of research attempting to introdu ce distributional measures in the
national accounts. The first national accounts in history—the famou s social tables of King
produced in the late 17th century—were in fact distributional national accounts, showing the
distribution of England’s income, consump t i o n , and saving across 26 social classes—from tem-
poral lords and baronets down to vagrants—in the year 1688 (see Barnet t , 1936). In the Uni t ed
States, Kuz n et s was interested in both national income and i ts distribut i o n and made path-
breaking advances on both fronts (Kuznets 1941, 19 53 ) .
3
His innovation wa s estimating top
income shares by combining tabulations of federal income tax returns—from wh i ch he derived
the income o f top earners using Pareto extrapolations—and newly constructed national accounts
series—that he used to compute the total incom e denominato r. Kuznets, however, did not fully
integra t e the two approa ches: his inequality series capture taxable income only and mis s all
tax-exempt cap i t al and labor income. The top income shares later computed by Piketty (2001,
2003), Piketty and Saez (2003), Atkinson (2005) and Alvaredo et al. (2011-2016) extended
Kuznets’ methodology to more countries and years but did not address this shortcoming.
Introdu ci n g distri b u t i on a l measures in the national accounts has received ren e wed i nterest
in recent years. In 2009, a report from the Commission on the Measurement of Economic Per-
formance an d Social Progress emphasized the impor t an c e of incl u d i n g distributional measures
such as household income quintiles in the Sy st em of National Account s (Stiglitz, Sen and Fi-
toussi, 2009). In response to th i s report, a number of countries, su ch as Australia, introduced
distributional statistics in their national accounts (Australian Bureau of Statistic, 2013) while
others are i n the process of doing so. Furlong (2014), Fixler and Johnson (2014), McCully
(2014), and Fixler et al. (2015) describe the ongoing U.S. effort, which focuses on scaling u p
income from the Cur re nt Population Survey to match personal income.
4
There are two main methodological differences between our paper and the work currently
conducted by statistical agencies. Fi r st , we start with tax data—rather than surveys—that we
supplement with surveys to capture forms of income that are not visible in tax returns, s u ch
as tax-exempt transfers. The use of tax data is critical to capture the to p of the d i st ri b u t i o n ,
3
Earlier attempts include King (1915, 1927, 1930).
4
Using tax data, Auten and Splinter (2016) have recently produced US income conc entration stati s t ic s since
1962 that improve upon the Piketty and Saez ( 2003) fiscal income series by distributing total personal income
(instead of total pre-tax and post-tax national income as we do here) from the national accounts. We view their
work as complementary to ou rs .
5
which ca n n ot be studied properly with s u rveys becau s e o f top-coding, insu ffi ci e nt over-sampling
of the top, sampling errors, or non-sam p l i n g errors.
5
Second, we are primarily inte re st ed in
the distribution of total n at i o n al income rather than household or personal income. National
income is in our view a m o r e meaningful starting point, because it is interna t i on a l l y comparable,
it is the aggregate used to comp u t e macroeconom i c growth, and it i s comprehensi ve, including
all forms of in co m e that eventually accrue to in d i v i d u a l s.
6
While we focus on national income,
our micro-files can be used to st u d y a wide range of income concepts, i n cl u d i n g the household
or perso n a l income concepts more traditionally analyzed.
Little work has contrasted the distributio n of pre-tax income with that of post -t ax income.
Top income sha r e studies only deal with pre-tax income, as many forms of transfers are tax-
exempt. Official income st a ti s ti c s fr om the Census Bureau focus on pre-tax income and include
only some government transfers (US Census Bureau 2016).
7
Congressional Bu d g et Office esti-
mates compute both pre-tax and post-tax inequality measures, but they include only Federal
taxes and do not try to incorporate government consumption (US Congressional Budget Office
2016). By contrast, we at t em pt to allocate all taxes (in cl u d i n g State and local taxes) and all
forms of government spending in order to provide a comprehensive view of how government
redistribution affects inequality.
Last, there is a large and growing theoretical literature jointly analyzing economic growth
and income dist ri b u t i o n . Historically, the Kuznets curve theory of how inequality evolves over
the path of development ( Ku zn e ts , 1955) came out of the seminal empirical work by Kuznets
(1953) on US incom e inequality. We hope that our estimates will similarly be fruitful to stimulate
future theoretical work on the interplay between growth and inequality.
8
5
Another possibil i ty would be to use the CPS as the baseline dataset and supplement it with tax data for the
top decile, where the CPS suffers from small samples, poorly measured capital income, and top-coding issues.
The advantage of starting from the CPS would b e that it has been the most widely known and used dataset to
analyze US income and wage inequality for many decades. We leave this alternative approach to future work.
6
Per son al income is a concept that is specific to the U.S . National Income and Product Accounts (NIPA).
It is an ambiguous concept (neither pre-tax, nor post-tax), as it does not deduct taxes but adds back cash
government transfers. The System of National Accounts (United Nations, 2009) does not us e personal income.
7
In our v i ew, not deducti n g taxes but counting (some) transfers is not conceptually meaningful, but it parallels
the definition of personal income in the US national accounts.
8
In recent decades, a lot of the work on inequality and growth has focused on the role of credit constraints
and wealth inequality (see, e.g., Galor and Zeira, 1992). Our data jointly capture wealth, capital income, and
labor income, making it possible to cast light on this debate and to study changes in the structure of inequality,
e.g., the extent to w hi ch there has truly been a demise of the capitalists-workers class structure (Galor and Moav
2006).
6
3 Methodolo gy to Distribute US N a ti ona l Income
In this section, we outline the main concepts and methodology we use to distribute US national
income. All the data sou r ce s and computer code we use are described in Online Appendix A;
here we focus on the main conceptual issues.
9
3.1 The Income Concept We Use: National Income
We are interested in the distribution of total national income. We fo l l ow the official definition of
national income codified in the latest System of National Accounts (SNA, United Nati on s, 2009),
as we do for all other national accounts concepts used in this paper. National i n co m e is GD P
minus capital dep r eci a t i on plus net income recei ved from abroad. Although macroeconomists,
the press, and the general public often focus on GDP, na t i on a l income is a more meaningful
starting point for two re aso n s. First, capital depreciation is not economic incom e: it does
not allow one to consume or accumulate wealth. Allocating depreciation to individuals woul d
artificially inflate the economic income of capital owners. Second, including foreign income is
important, because for ei gn dividends and interest are sizable f or top earners.
10
In moving away
from GDP and toward national income, we follow one of the recommendations m ad e by the
Stiglitz, Sen and Fitoussi (2009) commission and also return to the pre-World War II focus on
national income (King 1930, Kuzne ts , 1941).
The national income of the United States is the sum of all the labor i n co m e—t h e flow return
to human capital—and capital income—the flow ret u r n to non-human capital—that accrues
to U.S. resident individuals. Some parts of national income never show up on any person’s
bank account, but it is not a reason to ignore them. Two prominent examples are the imputed
rents of homeowners and taxes. First, there is an economic return to owning a house, whether
the house is rented or not; national income therefore includes bot h monetary rents—for houses
rented out —a n d im p u t ed rents—for owner-o ccu p i e rs . Secon d , some income is immediately pai d
to the government in the form of payroll or corporate ta x es, so that no individual ever feels it
9
A discussion of the general issues involved in creating distributional national accounts is presented in Al-
varedo et al. (2016). These guidelines are not specific to the United States but they are based on the lessons
learned from constructing the US distribut i on al national accounts presented here, and from similar on-going
projec t s in other countries.
10
National income also includes the sizable flow of undistributed profits reinvested in foreign companies that
are more than 10% U.S.-owned (hence are class i fie d as U.S. d ir e ct investments abroad). It does not, however,
include undistributed profits reinvested in foreign companies in which the U.S. owns a share of less than 10%
(classified as portfolio investments). Symme tr i cal l y, national income deducts all t h e primary income paid by the
U.S. to non-residents, including the undistributed profits reinvested in U.S. companies that are more than 10%
foreign-owned.
7
earns th a t fractio n of national income. But these taxes are part of the flow return to capital and
labor and as such accrue to the owners of the factors of production. The same is true for sales
and excise taxes. Out of their sales proceeds at market prices (including sales taxes), producers
pay workers labor income and owners cap i t al income but must also pay sales and excise taxes to
the government. Hence, sales and excise taxes are part of national income even if they are not
explicitly part of employee compensation or profits. Who exactly earns the fraction of nationa l
income pai d in the form of corporate, payroll, and sales taxes is a tax in ci d en c e question to
which we return in Secti on 3.3 bel ow. Although national income inclu d es all th e flow retur n
to the factors of production , it does not include the ch a n g e in the price of these factors; i.e., it
excludes the capital gains caused by pure asset price changes.
11
National in co m e is larger an d has been g r owing faster than the other income concepts tr ad i -
tionally used to study in eq u al i ty. Figure 1 provides a reconciliation betwe en national income—as
recorded in the national accounts—a n d the fiscal income reported by ind i v i d u a l taxpayers to the
IRS, for labor and capital income separately.
12
About 70% of national income is labor income
and 30% is capital income. Although most of national labor income is reported on tax returns
today, the gap between taxable labor income and national labor income has been growing over
the last several decades. Untaxed l a bor income includes tax-exempt fringe benefits, employer
payrol l taxes, the labor income of non filers (large before the early 1940 s) and unreported labor
income due to tax evasion. The fraction of labor income which is taxable has declined from 80%-
85% in the post-Wor l d War II decades to just under 70% in 2014, due to the rise of employee
fringe benefits. As for capital, on l y a third of total capital income is reported on tax returns.
In addition to the imp u t ed rents of homeowners and various taxes, untaxed capital income in-
cludes the di v i d end s and interest paid to tax-exempt pension accounts, and corporate retained
earnings. The l ow ratio of taxable to t ot a l capital income is not a new p h en o m eno n —t h er e is no
trend in this ratio over time. However, when taking into account both labor and capital incom e,
the fraction of national income that is reported in individual income tax da t a has declined from
70% in the late 1970s to about 60% today. This result implies that tax data un d er -e stimate
11
In the long-run, a large fraction of capit al gains arises fr om the fact that corporations retain part of their
earning, which leads to share price appreciation. Since retained earnings are part of national income, these
capital gains are in effect included in our series on an accrual basis. In the short run, however, most capital
gains are pure asset price effects. Thes e short-term capital gains are ex cl u de d from national income and from
our series.
12
A number of studies have tried to reconci l e totals from the national accounts and totals fr om household
surveys or tax data; see, e.g., Fesseau, Wolff and Mattonetti ( 2012) and Fesseau and Mattonetti (2013). Such
comparisons have long bee n conducted at nation al levels (for example, Atkinson and Micklewright, 1983, for
the UK) and th er e have been earlier cross country comparisons (for example in the OECD report by Atkinson,
Rainwater , and Smeeding, 1995, Section 3.6).
8
both the levels and growth rates of U.S. incomes. They particularly under-estimate growth for
the middle-class, as we shall see.
3.2 Pre-tax Income and and Post -ta x Income
At the individual level, income differs whether it is observed before or after the operation of th e
pension system and government redistribution. We therefor e define three inco m e concepts that
all add up to national income: pre-tax factor income, pr e-t a x national income, and post-t ax
national income. The key difference between pre-tax factor income and pre-tax nati on a l income
is the treatment of pensions, which are counted on a contribution basis for pre-tax factor income
and on a distribution basis for pre-tax national income. Post-tax nation a l income deducts all
taxes and adds back all publ i c spend i n g, including publi c goods consu m p t i on . By con st r u ct i on ,
average pre-tax facto r income, pre-tax national income, and post-tax national incom e are all the
same in our benchmark series (and equal to average nati o n al income), which makes comp ar i n g
growth rates straightforward.
Pre-tax factor income Pre-tax factor income (or more simply factor income) is equal to
the sum of all the income flows accruing to the individual owners of the factors of p r oduction,
labor and capital, before taking into accou nt the operation of pensions and the tax and transfer
system. Pension benefits are not included in factor income, nor is any form of private or public
transfer. Fact or income is also gross of all taxes and all contrib u t i o n s, including contri b u t i ons
to private pensions and Soci al Security. One problem with this con ce p t of income is that retired
individuals typically have littl e factor income, so that the inequality of facto r income tends to
rise mechanically with the fraction of old-age individuals in the popu l a ti o n , potentially bi as i n g
comparisons over time a n d across countries. Look i n g at the distribution of factor incomes can
however yield certain i n si ghts, especially if we restrict the analysis to the working-age popula ti o n .
For instance, it al l ows to measure the distribution of labor costs paid by empl oyers.
Pre-tax national income Pre-tax national income (or more sim p l y pre-tax income) is our
benchma rk concept to stu d y the distribution of income before government intervention. Pre-
tax income is equal to th e sum of all income flows going to labor and capital, after taking into
account the operation of private and public pensions, as well as disab i l i ty and unemployment
insurance, but before taking into account other taxes and transfers. That is, the only difference
with factor income is that we deduct the contributions to private an d public pensions includ i n g
Social Security—old age, survivors and disability—and unemployment insurance from incomes,
9
and add back the corresponding benefits.
13
Pre-tax income is broader but co n cep t u a l l y similar
to what the IRS attempts to tax, as pensions, S oci a l Security, and unemployment benefits are
largely taxable, while contributions are largely tax deductible.
14
Post-tax national income Post-tax nationa l income (or more simply post-tax income)
is equal to pre-tax income after subtracting all ta xes and adding all forms of government
spending—cash transfers, in-kind transfers, and collective con su m p t i on expenditures.
15
It is
the income that is available for saving and for the consumption of private and p u b l i c goods.
One advantage of allocati n g all forms of government spending to individual s—a n d not just cash
transfers—is that it ensures that post-tax income adds up to national income, just like factor
income and pre-tax income.
16
It can be useful, however, to focus on post-tax income including
cash transfer s transfers only—for instan ce to study the distribution of private co n su m p t i on .
We therefore define post-tax dispos abl e income as pre-tax national income minus all taxes plus
monetary transfers only. Post-tax disposable income does not add up t o national income but is
easier to measure than post-tax national income, bec au se it does not require allocatin g in-kind
transfers and collective consumption expenditure across the distribution.
Our objective is to construct the distrib u t i on of factor income, pre-tax income, a n d post-tax
income. To do so, we match tax data to survey data and make explicit assumptions about the
distribution of income categories for which there is no available source of informat i o n . We start
by describing how we move from fiscal income to total pre-tax income, before describ i n g how
we deal with taxes and tran s fer s to obtain post-tax income.
3.3 From Fiscal Income to Pre-Tax National Income
The starting point of our distribu t i on a l na t i on a l accou nts is the fiscal income reported by tax-
payers to the IRS on individual income tax returns. The main data source, for the post-1962
13
Cont r ib u t ion s to pensions include the capital income earned and reinvested in tax-exempt pension plans
and accounts. On aggregate, contributions to private pensions largely exceed distributions i n the United States,
while contributions to Social Security have been smaller than Social Security disbursements in re ce nt years
(see Appendix Table I-A10). To match national income, we add back the surplus or deficit to individu als ,
proportionally to wage income for private pensions, and proportionally to taxes paid and benefits received for
Social Security (as we do for the government deficit when computing post-tax income, see below).
14
Social Security benefits were fully tax exempt before 1984 (as well as unemployment benefits before 1979).
15
Social S ecu r i ty and unemployment insurance taxes were already subtracted in pre-tax income and the
corresponding benefits added in pre-tax income, so they do not need to be subtracted and added again when
going from pre-tax to post-tax income.
16
Government spending typically exceeds government revenue. I n order to match national income, we add
back to individuals the government deficit proportionally to taxes paid and benefit s received; see Section 3.4
below.
10
period, is the set of annual public-use micro-files created by the Statistics of Income division
of the IRS and available through the NBER that provide i n fo r m at i o n for a lar g e sample of
taxpayers with detailed income categories. We supplem ent this dataset using the internal use
Statistics of Income (SOI) Individual Tax Return Sample files from 1979 onward.
17
For the
pre-1962 period, no micro-files are available so we rely instead on the Piketty and Saez (2003 )
series of top in com es which were const r u ct ed from annual tabulations of income and its com-
position by si ze of income (U.S. Trea su r y Department , Internal Revenue Service, Statistics of
Income, 1916-present). Tax data contain information about most of the components of pre-
tax income, including private pension distrib u t i on s— th e vast majority of which are taxable—,
Social Security benefits (taxable since 1984), and unemployment compensation (taxable since
1979). However, they miss a growing fr act i o n of labor income and about two-thirds of economic
capital income.
Non-filers To sup p l em ent tax data, we start by adding synthetic observations rep r esenting
non-filing tax un i t s using the Current Population Survey (CPS). We identify non-filers in the
CPS based on their taxable income , and weight these observations such that the total number
of ad u l t s in our final dataset matches the total number of adults living in the United States, for
both the working-age population (aged 20-65) and the elderly.
18
Tax-exempt labor income To capture total pre-tax labor income i n the economy, we pro-
ceed as follows. First, we compute employer payroll taxes by applying the statutory tax rate
in each year. Second, we allocate non - t ax a b l e health and pension fringe benefits to individual
workers using i n fo r m ati o n reported in the CPS.
19
Fringe benefits have been r eported to the
17
SOI maintains high quality individual tax sample data since 1979 and population-wide data s in ce 1996. All
the estimates using internal data presented in this paper are gathered in Saez (2016). Saez (2016) uses intern al
data statisti cs to supplement the public use files with tabulat ed information on age, gender , earnings split for
joint filers, and non-fil er s characteristics which are used in this study.
18
The I RS receives information returns that also allow to estimate the income of non-filers. Saez (2016)
computes detailed statistics for non-filers using IRS data for the period 1999-2014. We have used these statistics
to adjust our CPS-based non-filers. Social security benefits, the major income category for non-filers, is very
similar in both CPS and IRS data and does not need adjustment. However, there are more wage earners and
more wage income per wage earner in the IRS non-filers statistics (perhaps due to the facts that very small
wage earners may report zero wage income in CPS). We adjust our CPS non-filers to match the IRS non-filers
char act e ri s ti c s; see Appendix Section B.1.
19
More precisely, we use the CPS to estimate the probability to be covered by a retirement or health plan in
40 wage bins (decile of the wage dist ri b ut i on × marital status × above or below 65 years old), and we impute
coverage at the micr o-l e vel using these es t i mat ed probabilities. For health, we then impute fixed benefits by
bin, as estimated from the CPS and adjusted to match the macroeconomic total of employer-provided health
benefits. For p en si ons , we assume that the contributions of pension plans participants are proportional to wages
winsorized at the 99th percent il e .
11
IRS on W2 forms in recent years—employee contributions to defined contribution plans since
1999, and health insurance since 2013 . We have che cked that our imputed pension benefits are
consistent with the high quality information reported on W2s.
20
They are also consistent with
the results of Pierce (2001), who studies non-wage compensat i on using a different dataset, the
employm e nt cost i n d ex micro-data. Like Pierce (2001) , we find that the changing dist r i b u t i on
of non-wage benefits has slightly reinforced the rise of wage inequ a l i ty.
21
Tax-exempt capital income To ca p t u r e total pre- t ax capital income in the economy, we first
distribute the total amount of household wealth r eco r d ed in the Financial Accounts following
the methodology of Saez and Zucman (2016). That is, we capitalize the interest, d i v i d en d s
and realized capital gains, rents, and business profits reported to the IRS to capture fixed-
income claim s, equ i t i es , tenant-occupied housing, and business assets. For itemizers, we impute
main homes and mortgage debt by capitalizin g property taxes and mo r tg a ge interest paid. We
impute all forms of wealth that do not generate repo rt a b l e income or deductions—currency,
non-mortgage debt, pensions, mun i ci p al bonds before 1986, a n d homes and mortgages for non-
itemizers—using the Survey of Consumer Finances.
22
Next, for each asset class we compute
a macroeconomic yield by dividing th e total flow of capital income by the total value of the
corresponding a sset . For instance, the yield on corporate equities is the flow of corporate
profits—distributed and retained—accruin g to U.S. reside nts di v i d ed by the market value of
U.S.-own ed equ i t i es. Last, we multiply indi v i d u al wealth components by the correspo n d i n g
yield. By construction, th i s procedure ensu r es that indiv i d u a l capital inc om e adds up to total
capital income in the economy. In effect, it blows up dividends and capital gains observed in
tax data in order to match the macro flow of corporate p r o fi t s including retained earnings—and
similarly for other asset classes.
Is i t reasonable to assume that retained earnings are distributed like dividends and realized
capital gains? The wealt hy might invest in compan i es that do not distribute di v i d en d s to
avoid the dividend tax, and they might never sell their shares to avoid the capital gains tax,
in which case retained earnings would be more concentrated than dividends and capital gains.
Income tax avoidance might also have changed over time as t o p dividend tax rates rose and
20
The Statistics of Income divis i on of the IRS produces valuable statistics on pension contributions reported
on W2 wage inc ome forms. In the future, our imputations could be refi n ed using individual level information
on pensions (and now health insurance as well) available on W2 wage income tax forms.
21
In our estimates, the share of total non-wage compensation earned by bottom 50% income earners has
declined from about 25% in 1970 to about 16% today, while the share of taxable wages earn ed by bottom 50%
income earners has fall en from 25% to 17%, see Appendix Table II-B15.
22
For complet e methodological details, see Sae z and Zucman (2016).
12
fell, biasi n g th e tren d s in our in eq u a l i ty series. We have investigated this issue careful l y an d
found no evidence that such avoidance behavior is quantitat i vely significant—even in periods
when top dividend tax rates were very high. Since 1995, there is comprehensive evidence from
matched estates-income tax returns that taxab l e rates of r et u r n on equity are similar across the
wealth distribution, suggesting tha t equities (hence retained earnings) ar e distributed similarly
to dividends and capital gains (Saez and Zucman 2016, Figure V). This also was true in the
1970s when top divi d en d tax rates were much higher. Exploi t i n g a publicl y available sample of
matched estates-income tax returns for people who died in 1976, Saez and Zucman (2016) find
that despi te facing a 70% top marginal inco m e tax rate, individuals in th e top 0.1% and top
0.01% of the wealth distribution had a high dividend yi el d (4.7%), almost as lar ge as the average
dividend yield of 5.1%. Even then , wealthy peop l e were unable or unwilling to disproportionally
invest in non-divid en d paying equities. These results suggest that allocat i n g retained earnings
proportionally to equity wea l t h is a reasonable ben chmark.
Tax incidence assumptions Computing pre-tax income requires making tax incidence as-
sumptions. Should the corporate tax, for instance, be fully added to corporate profit s, hence
allocated to shareholders? As is well known, the burden of a tax is not necessarily borne by
whoever nominally pays i t. Behavioral responses t o taxes can affect the relative price of factors
of production, thereby shifting the tax b u r d en from one factor to t h e other; taxes also genera t e
deadweig ht losse s (see Fullerton and Metcalf, 2002 for a survey). In this paper, we do not
attempt to measure th e complete effects of t axes on econ omi c behavior and the money- m et r i c
welfare of each individual. Rather, and perhaps as a reasonable first approximation, we make
the following simple assumptions regarding tax incidence.
23
First, we assume that taxes neither affect the overall level of national income nor its distri-
bution across labor a n d capital. Of course this is unli kely t o be true. An alternative stra t eg y
would be to make explicit assumptions about the elasticit i es of supply and demand for labor
and capital, so as to estimate what would be the counterfactual level of output and income
if the tax sy st em did not exist (one would also need to model how public infrastructures are
paid for, and how they contribute to the production functi on ) . This is beyond the scope of
the present paper and is left for future work. We prefer to adopt a more modest objective:
we s i m p l y assume that pre-tax and p o st -ta x income both add up to the same national income
total, and that taxes on capital are borne by capital only, while taxes on labor are borne by
23
For a detailed discussion of ou r tax incidence assumptions, see the Online Appendix Section B.4.
13
labor o n l y. In a standard tax inci d en ce model, th i s is indeed the case whene ver the elasticity e
L
of labor supply with r espect to the net-of-tax wage rate and the elastici ty e
K
of capital supply
with respect to the net-of-tax rate of return are small r el a t i ve t o the elasticity of substitution σ
between capital and labo r .
24
This implies, for instance, that payr o l l taxes are entirely paid by
workers, irrespective of whether they are nominally paid by employers or employees.
Second, within the capital sector , and consistent with the seminal analysis of Harberger
(1962), we allow for the cor porate tax to be shifted to forms of capital other than equitie s.
25
We di ffer from Harberger ’ s analy si s only in that we treat residential real estate separately.
Because the residential real estate m arket does not seem perfectly integrated with finan ci a l
markets, it seems more reasonable to assume that corporate taxes are borne by all capital
except residential real estate. We symmetrical l y assume that residential property taxes only fall
on residential real estate. Last, we assume that sales and excise taxes are paid proportionally
to factor income minus saving.
26
We have also tested a numbe r of alternative tax incidence
assumptions, and found only second-order effects on the level and time pattern of our pre-tax
income series .
27
Our incid en ce assumptions are broadly similar to the assump t i on s made by
the US Congressional Budget Office (2016) which produces di st r i b u t i on a l sta ti s ti c s for Fed er a l
taxes only.
28
Our micro-files are con st r u ct ed in such a way that users can make alternative
tax incidence assumptions. These assumptions might b e i m p r oved as we learn more abou t the
economic incidence of taxes. It is also worth noting that our tax incidence assumptions only
matter for the d i s tr i b u t i o n of pre-tax income—th ey do not matter for post-tax series, which by
definition subtract all taxes.
24
However whenever sup p ly effect s cann ot be neglected, the aggregate level of domestic output and national
income will be affected by the tax system, and all taxes will be partly shifted to both labor and capital.
25
Harberger (1962) shows t hat un d er reasonable assumptions, cap i t al bears exactly 100 percent of the cor porate
tax but that the tax is shifted t o all forms of capital.
26
In effect, this assumes that sales taxes are shifted to prices rather than t o the factors of production so
that they are borne by consumers. In practice, assumptions about the incidence of sales taxes make very little
difference to the level and trend of our income shares, as sales taxes are not very important in the Unite d Stat es
and have been constant to 5%-6% of national income since the 1930s; see Appendix Table I-S.A12b.
27
For instance, we tried allocating the corporate t ax to all capital assets including housing; allocating residential
property taxes to all capital assets; allocating consumption taxes proportionally to income (instead of income
minus savings). Non e of this made any significant difference.
28
CBO assumes t h at corporate taxes fall 75% on all forms of capital and 25% on labor income. Because U.S.
mul t i nat i on al firms can fairly easily avoid US taxe s by shifting profits to offshore tax havens without having to
chan ge t h ei r actual production decisi on s ( e. g. , through the manipulation of transfer prices), it does not seem
plausible to us that a significant share of the US corporate tax is borne by labor (see Zucman, 2014). By contrast,
in small countries—where firms’ l ocation decisions may be more elastic—or in countries that tax capital at the
source but do not allow firms to easily avoid taxes by artificially shifting profits offshore, it is likely that a more
sizable fraction of cor porate taxes fall on labor.
14
3.4 From Pre-Tax Income to Post-Tax Income
To move from pre-tax to post-tax inco m e, we deduct all taxes and add back all government
spending. We incorporate all levels of government (federal, state, and local) in our analysis of
taxes and government spending, which we decompose into monetary transfers, in-kin d transfers,
and collect i ve consumption expenditure. Using our micro-files, it is p o ssi b l e to separate federal
from state and local taxes and spending.
Monetary social transfers. We impute all monetar y social transfers d i r ectl y to recipients.
The main monetary transfers are the earne d income tax credit, the aid for families with de-
pendent children (which became the t em porary aid to needy famili es in 1996), food stamps,
29
and supplementary security income. Together, they make about 2.5% of n at i o n al income, see
Appendix Table I-S.A11. (Remember that Social security pensions, unemployment insu r a n ce,
and disability benefits, which together make about 6% of national i n com e , are already included
in pre–tax in co me) . We imp u t e monetary transfers to their beneficiaries based on rules and
CPS data.
In-kind social transfers. In-kind social tra n sfe rs are all transfers that are not mon et a r y (or
quasi-monetary) but are individualized, that is, go to specific beneficiaries. In-k i n d transfers
amount to about 8% of nationa l income today. Almost all in-kind t r an sf er s in the United
States correspond to health benefits, primarily Medicare and Medicaid. Beneficiaries are again
imputed based on rules (such as all persons aged 65 and above or persons receiving disability
insurance for Medicare) or based on CPS data (for Medicaid). Medicare and Medicaid benefits
are imputed as a fixed amount per beneficiary at cost value.
Collective expenditure (public goods consumption). We allocate collective consump-
tion ex penditure proportionall y to post-tax disposa b l e income. Given that we know relatively
little about wh o benefits from spending on defense, police, the justice system , infrastructure,
and the like, this seems like the most reasonable ben chmark t o sta r t wi th . It has the advantage
of being neutral: our post-tax income sha re s are not affected by the allocation of public good s
consumption. There are of course other possi b l e ways of allocating public g ood s . The two polar
cases would be distributing public goods equally (fixed amount p er adult), and proportionally
29
Food stamps (renamed supplementary nutrition assistance pr ogr ams as of 2008) is not a monetary transfer
strictly speaking as it must be used to buy food but it is almost equivalent to cash in practice as food exp e nd it ur es
exceed benefits for most families (see Currie, 2003 for a survey).
15
to weal t h (which might be justifiabl e for some types o f public goods, such as police and defense
spending). An equal allocation would increase the level of income at the bottom, but wou l d not
increase its growth, because pu b l i c goods spending has been constant around 18% of n a t i on a l
income since the end of World War II. Our tr ea t m ent of public goods could easil y be im p r oved
as we learn more about who benefits from them.
In our benchmark series, we also allocate pub l i c education co n su m p t i o n expenditure pro-
portionally to post-tax disposable income.
30
This can be justified from a lifetime per spective
where everybody benefits from education and where higher earners attended better schools and
for longer. In the Online Appendix Sect i on B. 5. 2 , we propose a polar alternative where we con-
sider the current parents’ perspective and attribute education spending as a fix lump sum per
child.
31
This slightly increases the level of bottom 50% post-tax incomes but without affecting
the trend.
32
Government deficit Government revenue usually does not add u p to total government ex-
penditure. To match national income, we impute the primary government deficit to individuals.
We alloca t e 50% of the deficit proportionall y to taxes paid, and 50% p r oportionally to bene-
fits received. This effectively assumes that any government defici t will translate into increased
taxes and reduced government spending 50/50. The imputation of the deficit does not affec t
the distribut i on of in c om e much, as taxes and government spending are both p r o gr es si ve, so
that increasing taxes and reducing government spending by the same amount has little net dis-
tributional effect. However, imputin g the deficit affects real growth, especiall y when the deficit
is large. In 2009-2011, the government deficit was aro u n d 10% of national income, abo u t 7
points higher than usual. The growth of post-tax incomes would have been much stronger in
the aftermath of th e Great Recession had we not allocated the defi ci t back to individuals.
33
30
That is, we treat government spending on education as government spending on other pu bl i c goods such as
defense and police. Note that in the Sy st em of National Accounts, public education consumption expenditure are
included in individual consumpti on expenditure (together with public health spending) rather than in c ol le ct i ve
consumption expenditure.
31
For married couples, we attribute each child 50/50 to each parent. Note that children going to college and
supported by parents are typically claimed as dependents so that our lump-sum measure gives more income to
families supporting children thr ou gh college.
32
See Appendix Figure S.23.
33
Int er es t income paid on government debt is included in individ ual pre-tax income but is not part of national
income (as it is a transfer from government to debt holders). Hence we also de du ct inter es t income paid by the
government to US residents in proportion to taxes paid and benefits received (50/50).
16
4 The Distributi on of National Income
We st ar t the analysis with a description of the levels and trends in pre-tax income and post-tax
income across the di st r i b u t i on . The unit of obser vation is the adult, i.e., the U.S. resident age d
20 and over.
34
We use 20 years old as the age cut-off—instead of the official majority age,
18—as many young adults still depend on their parents. Throughout this section, the income
of marri ed couples is split equ al l y between spouses. We will analyze how assigning each spouse
her or his own l abor in com e affects the results in Section 5.1.
4.1 The Distribution of Pre-Tax and Post-Tax Income in 2014
To get a sense of the distribution of pre-tax and post-tax national in co m e in 2014, consider first
in Table 1. Average income per adult in the United States is equal t o $64,600—by definition, for
the ful l adult population, p r e- t ax and post-tax average nation a l incomes are the same. But this
average masks a great deal of heterogeneity. The bottom 50% adults ( m or e than 117 mi l l i on
individuals) earn on average $16,200 a year before taxes and transfers, i.e., about a fourth of the
average income economy wide. Accordingly, the bottom 50% receives 12.5% (a fourth of 50%)
of total national pre-tax income. The “middle 40% ”—the group of adults with income be tween
the median and the 90th percentile that can be described as the middle class—has roughly the
same average pre-tax income as the economy-wide average. That is, the pre-tax income share
of the mi d d l e 40% is close to 40%. The top 10% earns 47% of total pre-tax income, i.e., 4.7
times the average income. There is thus a ratio of 1 to 20 between average pre-tax income in
the top 10% and in the bottom 50%. For context , this is much more than the ratio of 1 to 8
between average income in the United States and average income in China—about $7,750 per
adult in 2013 using market exchange rates to convert yuans into dollars.
35
Moving further up
the income distribution, the top 1% earns abou t a fifth of total national income (20 times the
34
We i n cl ud e the institutionalized population in our base population. This includes prison inmates (about
1% of adult population in the US), population living in old age institutions and mental institutions (about
0.6% of adult populat i on) , and the homeless. The instit u t i onal i ze d population is generally not covered by
surveys. Furlong (2014) and Fixler et al. (2015) remove the income of ins ti t u t ion al i zed households from the
national account aggregates to construct their distributional series. We prefer to take everybody into account
and allocate zero incomes to institutionalized adults when they h ave no inc ome. Such adults file tax returns
when they earn income.
35
All our results in this paper use the same national income price index across the US income distribution
to compute real income, disregar di n g any potenti al differences in prices across groups. Using our micr o-fi le s, it
woul d be straightforward to use different price index es for different groups. This might be desirable to study the
inequality of consumption or standards of living, which is not the focus of the current paper. Should one deflate
income differently across the distribution, then one should also use PPP-adjusted exchan ge rates to compare
average US and Chinese income, r ed u ci ng the gap between the two countries to a ratio of approximately 1 to 5
(instead of 1 to 8 using market price exchan ge rates).
17
average income) and the top 0.1% close to 10% (100 times the average income, or 400 times the
average bottom 50% income). The top 0.1% income share is close to the bottom 50% sh ar e.
Post-tax nation a l incom e is more equally distri b u te d than pre-ta x incom e: the t a x and
transfer syst em is progressive overall. Transfers play a key role for the bottom 50%, where
post-tax national income ($25,000) is over 50% higher than pre-tax national income. This
is, however, entirely due to in-ki n d transfers and collective expenditures: post-tax disposable
income—including cash transfers but excluding in-kind transfers or public goods—is onl y slightly
larger than pre-tax nation a l income for the bott om 50%. That is, th e bottom 5 0 % pays roughly
as much in taxes as what it receives in cash transfers; it does not benefit on net from cash
redistribution. While the bottom 50% earns a bo u t 40% of the average post-tax inc om e, the
top 10% earns cl o se to 4 times the average post-tax income (i.e., the top 10% post-tax share
is 39%). After taxes and transfers, ther e i s thus a ratio of 1 to 10 between the average income
of the top 10% and of bottom 50%—still a larger difference than the ratio of 1 to 8 between
average national income in the United States and in China. Taxes and government spending
reduce top 10% incomes by about 17 % , top 1% incomes by 23%, and top 0.1%, top 0.01%, and
top 0 . 00 1% incomes by abo u t 27%. Taken together, government taxes and transfers are overall
slightl y progressive at the top.
In Appendix Table S.7, we also report the distr i b u t i on of factor in co m e, that is, income
before any tax, transfer, and before the operation of the pension system. Unsurpri s i n gl y, since
most re ti r ee s have close to zero factor income, the bottom 50% factor income share is lower
than the bot t o m 50% pre-tax income sh a re , by abou t two points. Th e average factor in co m e of
bottom 50% earners i s $13,300 in 2014, significantly less than their average post-tax dispo sa b l e
income. That is, if one uses facto r income as the benchmark series for the distributio n of
income befor e government intervent i on , then the bottom 50% appear s as a net beneficiary of
cash redistri b u ti o n . For the top 10% and above, factor income and pre-tax income are almost
identi ca l as social security and pensions are a very small fract i on of income at the top.
4.2 Long-Run Trends in the Distribution of Income and Growth
There have been considerable lon g-r u n chan ges in income inequality in the United States over
a century. Figure 2 displays the share of pre-tax and post-tax inco m e going to the top 10%
and top 1% adults. Top pre-tax income shar es fell in the first half of the twentiet h century
and have been rising rap i d l y since the early 1980s. Pre-tax top income shares are a l m os t at the
same level today as they were at their peak in the late 1920s just before the Great Depress i on .
18
The U-shaped evolution over the last century is similar to the one seen in fiscal income series
(Piketty and Saez, 2003), although there are differences, as we explain in Section 6 where we
reconcile our findings with other estimates of US income inequality.
Top post-tax income shares have also followed a U-shaped evol u t i o n over time, but exhibit
a less marked upward swing in recent decades. In particular, they have not return ed to their
level of a century ago. Early in the twentieth century, when the government was sma l l an d
taxes low, post-tax and pre-tax top incomes were similar . Pre-tax and post-tax shares started
divergi n g during the New Deal for the top 1% and World Wa r II for the top 10%—when federal
income taxes increased significantly for that group as a whole. And although post-tax inequality
has incr ea sed significantly since 1980, it has risen less than pre-tax inequality. Between 1980
and 2014, the top 10% income share rose by about 10 points post-tax and 13 points pre-tax.
As a result of the si g n i fi ca nt 2013 tax increases at the top, post-t a x top income shares have
increased less than pre-tax income shares in very recent years. Overall, redistributive polici es
have p r evented post-tax inequality from returning all the way to pre-New Deal levels.
Table 2 decom po ses growth by income groups since World War II in two 34 year long sub-
periods. From 1946 to 1980, real macroeconomic growth per adult was strong (+95%) and
equally distributed—in fa ct , it was slightly equalizing, as bo t to m 90% grew faster than top
10% incomes.
36
In the next 34 years period, from 1980 to 2014, aggregat e growth slowed down
(+61%) and became extremely uneven. Looking first at income before taxes and trans fer s,
income stagnated for bottom 50% earners: for this group , average pre-tax income was $16, 00 0
in 1980—expressed in 20 1 4 dollars, u si n g the national income deflator—and still is $16,200 in
2014. Growth for the mi d d l e 40% was weak, with a pre-tax incr eas e of 42% since 1980 (0.8% a
year). At th e top, by contrast, average income mo r e than doubled for the top 10%; it tripled for
the top 1%. The further one moves up the ladder, the high e r the growth rates, culminating in an
increase of 636% for the top 0.001%—ten times the macroeconomic growth rate. Such sharpl y
divergent growth experiences over decades hi g h l i g ht the need for growth statistics disaggregated
by income groups.
Government redistribution made growth more equitable, but only slightly so. After taxes
and transfers, the bottom 50% only grew +21% since 1 98 0 (0.6% a year). That is, transfers
erased about a third of the gap between macr oeconomic growth (+60%) and growth at th e
bottom (0% before government intervention). Taxes did not hamper the u p s u rg e of income at
the top: after taxes and transfers the top 1% nearly doubled, the top 0.1% nearly tripled, the
36
Very top incomes, however, grew more in post-tax terms then in pre-t ax terms between 1946 and 1980,
because the tax system was more progressive at the very top in 1946.
19
top 0.001% grew 617% , almost as much as pre-tax.
4.3 The Stagnation of Bottom 50% Average Income
Perhaps the most striking develo p m ent in the U.S. ec on o my over the last decades is the stagna-
tion of income in the bottom 50%. This evolution therefore deserves a careful analysis.
37
The
top panel of Fi gu r e 3 shows how the pre-tax and post-tax income shares of the botto m 50%
have evolved since the 1960s. The p r e-t a x share increased in the 19 60s as the wage d i st r i b u t i on
became more equal—the real federal minimum wage rose significantly in th e 1960s and reached
its historical ma x i mum in 1969. The pre-tax share th e n declined from about 21% in the 1969
down to 12.5% in 2014. The post - ta x share initially increased more then the pre-tax share
followin g President Johnson’s “war on poverty”—the Food Stamp Act was passed in 1965; aid
to families with dependent children increased in the second half of the 1960s, Medi ca i d was
created in 1965 . It then fell along with th e pre-tax income share. The gap between the pre-
and p ost - ta x share of income ea rn e d by the bottom 50% incr ea sed over time. This is not due
to the growth of Social Security benefits—because pre-tax income includes pension and social
security benefi t s—b u t owes to the rise of transfers other than Social Security, chiefly Medicaid
and Medicare. In fact, as shown by the bottom panel of Figure 3, almost all of the meager
growth in real bottom 50% post-tax income since the 1970s comes from Medicare and Medi-
caid. Excluding those two transfers, average bottom 50% post-tax income would have stagnated
around $20,000 since the late 1970s. The bottom half of the adult population has thus been
shut off from econom i c growth fo r over 40 years, and the paltry increase in their disposable
income has been absorbed by increased health spending.
The growth in Medicare and Medicaid transfers reflects an increase in the generosity of the
benefits, but also the rise in the price of health serv i ce s provided by Medicare and Medi cai d —
possibly above what people would be willing to pay on a private market (see, e.g. , Finkel-
stein, Hendren, and Luttmer 20 16 )— an d perh ap s an increase in the econom i c surplus of health
provid er s in the medical a n d pharmaceutical sectors. To put in perspecti ve the average annual
health trans fer of about $5,000 received by bottom 50% individuals, note that it represent s the
equivalent of less than a week of the average pre-tax income of top 10% individuals (about
$300,000) and a bit more than a day of the average pre-tax income of top 1% individual s ($1.3
37
There is a large literature documenting the stagnation of low-skill wage earnings (see, e.g., Katz and Autor,
1999). The US Census bureau (2016) official statistics also show very little growt h of median family income in
recent decades. Our value added is to include all national income accruing to the bottom 50% adults, to contrast
pre-tax and post-tax incomes, and to be able to compare the bottom to the top of the distribu t ion in a single
dataset representative of th e US population.
20
million). Concretely, the in-kind health redistribu ti o n received by botto m 50% individuals is
equivalent to about one week of attention provided by an average top-decile health provider, or
one day of attention provided by an average top-percentile health provider.
Figure 3 also di sp l ays the average post-tax disposable income of bottom bottom 50 % earners—
including cash transfers but excluding in-kind transfers and collecti ve consumption expen d i -
tures. For the bottom half of the distribution, post-tax disposabl e income has stagnated at
about $15,000–$17,000 since 19 8 0. This is about the same level as average bottom 50% pre-tax
income. In other words, it is solely through in-kind health transfers and collective expenditure
that the bottom half of the distribution s ees it s in co m e ri se a bove i t s pr e-t a x l evel and beco m es
a net beneficiary of redistribution. In fact, until 2008 the bottom 50% paid more in taxes than
it received in cash transfers. The post-tax disposable in co m e of bottom 50% adults was lifted
by the large government deficits run during the Great Recession: Post-tax disposable income
fell much less than post-tax income—which imputes the deficit back to individuals as negative
income—in 2007-2010.
From a purely logical standpoint, t h e sta gn a t i on o f bottom 50% income might reflect d em o -
graphic cha n g es ra th e r tha n d eeper evolutions in the distribution of li fet i m e in c om es. People’s
incomes tend to first rise with age—as workers build human capital and acquire experience—an d
then fall during retirement, so population aging may have pushed the bottom 50% income share
down. It would be interesting to estimate how the bottom 50% lifet i m e in c om e has changed
for different cohorts.
38
Existing estimates suggest that mob i l i ty in earnings did not increase
in the lo n g- ru n (see Kopczuk, Saez, and Song, 2010 for an analysis using Socia l Security wage
income data), so it seems unlikely that the increase in cross-sectional in co m e inequality—an d
the colla p se in the bottom 50% income shar e—co u l d be offset by rising lifetime mobility out of
the bot t o m 50%.
To shed more light on this issue, we have computed the evolution of bottom 50% incomes
within different age gro u p s separately.
39
For the working-age population, as shown by the top
panel of Figure 4, t h e average botto m 50% income rises with age, from $13,000 for adults aged
20-44 to $23,000 for adults aged 45-65 in 2014—st i l l a very low level. But the most striking
finding is that among worki n g- ag e adults, average bottom 50% pre-tax income has collapsed
since 1980: -20% for adults aged 20-45 and -8% for those between 45 and 65 years o l d . It is only
38
In our view, both the annual and lifetime perspective are valuable. This paper focuses on the annual
persp e ct i ve. It captures cross-sectional inequality, which is particularly relevant for lower income groups that
have l im i te d ability to smooth fluctuations in income through saving. Constructing life-time inequality series is
left for future re sear ch.
39
We can do this decomposition by age star t i ng in 1979 when age data become available in internal tax data.
21
for the elderly that pre-tax income has been rising, because of the increase in Social Security
benefits and private pensions distributions. Americans aged above 65 and in the bott o m 50%
of that age group now have the same average income as all bottom 50% adults—about $16,000
in 2014—whi l e they earned much less in 1980.
40
After taxes and transfers, as shown by the
bottom panel of Figure 4, the average income of bottom 50% seniors now exceeds t h e average
bottom 50% income in the full population and has grown 70 % since 1980. In fact, all the
growth in post-tax bottom 50% income owes to the increase in income for the elderly.
41
For the
working -a ge population, post-tax botto m 50% income has hardly increased at all since 1980 .
We reach the same conclusion when we look at the average pos t-t ax disposabl e income of the
bottom 50% adults aged 20 to 45: it has stagnated at very low levels—around 15,000$ .
There are thr ee main lessons. First, since income has coll ap se d for the bottom 50% of all
working -a ge groups—including experienced workers above 45 years old—it is unlikely that the
bottom 50% of lifetime income has grown much since the 1980s. Second, the stagnation of the
bottom 50 % is not due to population aging—quite t h e contrary: it is onl y the income o f the
elderly which is r i si n g at the bo t to m . For the bottom half of the working-age po p u l at i o n , average
income befo r e government intervention has fallen since 19 80 —t h i s is true whether one looks at
pre-tax income (including Social Security benefits) or factor income (excluding Social Secur i ty
benefits).
42
Third, despite the rise in m ean s -t est ed benefits—includi n g Medicaid and the Earned
Income Tax Credit, created in 1975 and expanded in 1986 and the early 1990s—government
redistribution has not enhanced income growth for low- an d moderate income wor k i n g- ag e
Americans over the last three decades. There are clear limits to what taxes and transfers can
achieve in the face of such massive changes in the pre-tax distribution of income li ke those that
have occurred since 1980. In our view, the main conclusion is that the policy discussion sh o u l d
focus on h ow to equalize the distribution o f primary assets, including human capital, financial
capital, and bargaining power, rather than merely ex-post redistribution.
The stagnation of income for th e bottom 50% contrasts sharply with the up su r g e of th e top
40
The vast majority—about 80% today—of the pre-tax i n come for bottom 50% elderl y Americans is pension
benefits. Howeve r, the income from salaried work has been growing over time and now accounts for about 12%
of the pre-tax income of poor elderly Americans (close to $2,000 on average out of $16,000); the r es t is accounted
for by a small c apit al income residual. See Appendix Table II-B7c.
41
In turn, most of the growth of the post-tax income of bot t om 50% elderly Americans has been due to
the rise of health benefits. Without Medicare and Medicaid (which covers nursing home costs for poor elderly
Americans), average post-tax income for the bottom 50% seni ors would have stagn at ed at $20,000 since the early
2000s, and would have increased only modestly since the early 1980s when it was around $15,000; see Appendix
Table II-C7c and Appendix Figure S.5.
42
More broadly, for the working-age p opu l at ion , growth is nearly identical whether one looks at factor income
or pre-tax income. For det ai l ed series on the distribution of factor income, see Appendix Tables II-A1 to II-A14.
22
1%. As shown by the top p a n el of Figure 5, both groups have basically switched their income
share. The top 1% used to earn 1 1% of national income in the late 1960s and now earns sl i ghtly
over 20% while the bottom 50% used to get slightly over 20% and now gets 12%. Eight points of
national income have been transferred from the bottom 50% to the top 1%. The top 1 % income
share has made gains large enough to more than compensate the fall in the bottom 50% share,
a group demogr a p h i cal l y 50 times larger.
43
While average pre-tax income has stagnated since
1980 at around $16,000 fo r the bottom 50%, it has been multiplied by three for the top 1% to
about $1, 30 0 , 00 0 in 2014 (bottom panel of Figure 5). As a r esu l t , while top 1% adults earned 27
times m or e income than bottom 50% adults on average in 1980, they earn 81 times more today.
Income is booming at the top for all groups, not only for the elderly. As shown by Appendix
Figure S.11, the top 0.1 % income share rises as much for adults aged 45 to 64 as for the entire
population. Population aging plays no role in the upsurge in US i n co m e concentration.
5 Decompos i ng Inequality: The Role of Gender, Capital,
and Government Redistribution
In this section, we use our distributional national accounts to provide a number of new decom-
positions that shed light on some of the key forces shaping the distribution of US incomes. We
start by studying the effect of changes in gender inequality, befo r e moving to changes in capital
vs. labor factor shares, and government taxes and t r an s fer s.
5.1 Gender Inequality and the Gla s s Ceiling
So far we have split income equally between spouses. In this section we present individualized
series where each spouse is assigned h i s or her own labor income.
44
By construction, individ-
ualized series assign zero labor in com e to a non-working spouse; comparing individualized and
equal-split series thus makes it possible to assess th e effect o f changes in women labor forc e
participation—and ge n d er inequality generally—on the evolution of income inequality. To sp l i t
earnings, we use infor m at i o n from W2 forms on the labor income earned by each spou se from
43
The next 40% “mi dd l e class” has also lost about 5.5 points of nat i on al income since 1980 while the upper
middle class, the top 10% exclu di n g the top 1% has gained about 3 points since 1980 (see Appendix Table II-B1).
44
Equal splitti n g implicitly assumes that all income earned by married couples is shared equally. Individualized
series by cont ras t assume that labor income is not shared at all. There is obviously a lot of variations across
couples in the actual sharing of resour ces and division of monetary power. E mp ir i cal studies find that ac t ual
sharing practices are in between full and no sharing (see Chiapp or i and Meghir, 2015, for a recent survey).
Because of the lack of compreh en si ve data (and esp ec i all y his t ori cal d at a) , we restrict ou rs el ves to the two polar
cases of full and no-sharing. Attempti n g to split i nc omes usin g empi r ic al shar in g rul es is left for fut u re re sear ch.
23
1999 onward. Prior to 1999, we rely on IRS tabulations of how wage income is split among
couples in the top 5% that are available for some years, and on similar tabulations that we
computed annually in the CPS for the bottom 95%.
45
We always split the capital income of
married couples equally, due to the lack of information on property regimes.
46
The long-run U-shaped evolution of pre-tax inequality is still present when assigning each
spouse her or his own labor income, but it is less marked. Unsurprisingly, there is always more
inequality when labor i n com e is assign ed to each spou se ind i vi d u a l l y rat h er th a n equa l l y spl i t .
But as shown by the top panel of Figure 6, the difference has varied a lot over time. When
women labor force pa r ti c i p at i o n was low in the 1950s an d 1960s, t h e top 10% income share
with in d i v i d u a l i zed labor income was su b s ta ntially higher than the top 10% s h ar e with incomes
equally split (+5 points). The gap has declined with the re d u cti o n i n gender inequality, to about
2 points tod ay. Individualized series therefore show a smaller rise in in com e con centration.
Income concentration in the late 1920s was worse than today on an i n d i v i d u al basis because
there was much more inequality within couples than today. The reduction in the gender gap
has played an important role in mitigating the rise of inequa l i ty.
The bottom panel of Figure 6 quantifies the ext ent to which the gender gap in earnings
has shrunk sin c e the 1960s. We take the total average pre-tax labor income of working-age
(20-64) men and divide it by the total average pre-tax labor income of working-ag e women.
This measu r e of the gend e r gap is la rg er than the one traditiona l l y used—the ratio between
men and women’s wage conditional on full-time work; see, e.g., Blau and Kah n (2016)—as it
includes n ot only wage differences conditional on working, but also differences in labo r force
participation, hours of work, fringe benefits, a n d self-employment income. This is the relevant
measure to study overall inequali ty among a d u l ts .
47
We find that men earned 3.7 times more
labor income than women in the early 1960s and now earn abou t 1.75 times more. The gender
gap in labor income has halved but has not disappeared—far from it. Additional breakdowns
by age show that the gender gaps incr ea se with age. In recent years, among adults ag ed 20-34,
men earn 1.3 times more than women; the ratio reaches about 2 for adults a ged 55 to 64; see
Appendix Figure S.7.
45
See Online Appendix Section B.2 for details. Since 1979, internal IRS data also provide the exact breakdown
for self-employment income acr oss spouses (see Saez, 2016).
46
Wealth acquired during marriage is generally jointly owned. J oi nt ownership means wealth is equally split in
case of divorce in community property states, like Texas and California. I n other states, joint ownership means
weal t h is “equitably distributed” in case of divorce, which might take into account relative contributions and
also give more to the spouse with less earning potential. Beques t s received and pre-marriage assets are generally
not equally split.
47
There is a wide literature on the US gender gap. See e. g. Blau, Ferber, and Wink le r (2014) for a classical
textbook treatment.
24
In the workin g -a ge population (including non-workers), at the median, pre-ta x labor income
differences between men and women have diminished. As shown by the top panel of Figure 7,
two forces are at play. For working-age women, the median pre-tax income has been multi-
plied by more than five from 1962 to 2014—largely the result of an increase in formal market
labor supply—to about $20,000 today. For working-age men, median pre-tax labor income has
stagnated: it is the same in 2014 as i n 1964, about $35,000. There has been no growth for
the media n male worker over half a century. The median labor i n co m e of men grew relatively
quickl y from 1962 to 1973 and during the 1990s boom, but fell during recessions, effectively
erasing all the ga in s. It collapsed, in particular, during the Great Recession, from $4 0 , 00 0 in
2007 to $33,000 in 2010. The medi an labor income of women has stopped growing since the
late 1990s, halting the convergence across genders. For all working-age individuals, as a result,
median pre-tax labor income is o n l y 10% higher in 20 14 ($27,500) than 25 years earlier in 198 9
($25,000).
Considerable g en d er inequalities persist at the top of the distribution. As the bottom panel
of Figure 7 shows, women are almost as likely to work as men today. The share of women among
the population earning posit i ve labor income—from salaried work or self-employment—was 37%
in the 1 9 60 s and converged to close to 50% d u r i n g the 1970s and 1980s—women have closed
the partici p at i o n gap. But women a r e much less represented in top labor income groups. In the
1960s, women accounted for less tha n 5% of the top 10%, top 1%, and top 0.1% labor income
earners. Nowadays they account for close to 27% of top 10% labor income earners (+22 points),
but the increase is smaller the higher one moves up the distribution, so that the proport i on of
women in top groups falls steeply with income. Wom en make only about 16% of the top 1%
labor income earners (+13 points since the 1960s), and 11% of the top 0.1% (+9 points). The
represent a ti v i ty of women at the very top has only modestly increased since 1999. The glass
ceiling is not yet close to being shattered.
48
5.2 Decomposing Inequality at the Top: Labor vs. Capital
Pre-tax income Y can be decomposed into a labor income component Y
L
and a capital in com e
component Y
K
. By definition, Y = Y
L
+ Y
K
. The share of national i n co m e accruing to capital
48
A number of studies have analyzed the share of women in top earnings gr oup s. Kopczuk, Saez, and Song
(2010), Figure X, use Social Security data from 1937 to 2004. Because of data limitations, they focus only
on commerce and industry employees leaving out all government workers (where women are over-repr esented
particularly in the education sector) and the self-employed. Guvenen et al. (2014) also use Social Security wage
earnings and obtain similar results. Atkinson et al. (2016) study the share of women i n top income groups in a
sample of 8 c ountries with individual taxation, but do not consider l abor income and capital income separately.
25
is α = Y
K
/Y and the labor share is 1 α = Y
L
/Y . Our di st r i b u t i on a l national accounts
make it possibl e to compute factor shares for each quantile of t h e distribution consistent with
macroeconomic factor shares.
49
This comprehensive definition of capital income is much broader
than capital income reported on tax retu r n s. In particular, it includes the imputed rents of
homeowne rs , property taxes, the returns on pension funds, corporate retained earn i n gs, and
corporate taxes.
For the United States as a whole, the capita l share of national income fluctuates around 20 %
to 30% and has been rising in recent decades, a phenomenon also observed in oth er cou ntries
(Piketty and Zucman 2014; Karabarbounis and Neiman 2014). In 2000, 23% of national income
was derived from capital; this share increased to 30% in 2014. In fact, as shown by Appendix
Table S.2, alm ost all the 2000- 20 14 growth of average income per adult in the United States
(0.6% a year on average over this period of time) owes to the rise of capita l in co m e: labor income
per adult has grown by 0.1% per year, while capital income per adult has grown by 2.2% per
year.
The capital share varies widely across the income distribution. The vast majority of Amer-
icans earn little ca p i t al income. As shown by the top panel of Figur e 8, for th e bottom 90%,
the capital share is always less than 20%. It has signific antly increased over time, from around
10% from the 1970s to close to 20% today—in large part because of the rise of pension funds,
which account for a growing share of household wealth (36% in 2014). Th e capital sh ar e then
rises steeply as one moves up the incom e di st ri b u t i o n . In 2014, the top 1% derives over half
of t h ei r incomes from capital, the top 0.1% more than two thirds. At the very top, the fluc-
tuations in the capital share are spectacular. Early in the twentieth century, th e top 0.1%
derived 70%-80% of its income from capital; this share collapsed during the Great Depression
when c or porate profits slumped, before rebounding in the 1950s and 1960s to up to 90%. In
other words, in the post-World War II decades, the top of the distribution was dominated by
“rentier s” . The working rich then replaced the rentiers from the 1970s to the late 1990s; this
process culminated in 2000 when t h e c ap i t a l share in the top 0.1% reached a low water-mark
of 48.5%. Since then, it has bounced back. As the 21st century progresses, the working rich of
49
To decomp os e the mixed income of non-corporate businesses into a labor an d a capital component, we assume
fixed factor shares for simplicity (namely 0.7 for labor income and 0.3 for capital income). This assumption is
irrelevant for our results on trends in income levels, income shares, and growth decompositions. It has very little
impact on the level and time patterns of capital shares. We experimented with other methods to decompose
mixed income. For instance, one can assume the same factor shares in the non-corporate sector as in the corporate
sector; or one can attr ib u te to the human capital—education and experience—of self-employed workers the same
return as the one observed for wage earners; or one can attribute to the non-human assets used by non-corporate
businesses the same rate of return as the one observed on other assets. This makes very little difference on the
total capital share, see Appendix Table I-S.A3.
26
the late twentieth century may increasingly live off their capital income, or be i n the process of
being replaced by their offsprings living off their inheritance.
One potential concern with th e computation of fa ct or shares is that the frontier between
labor and capital can be fu zzy. In closely held businesses, owner-manager s can choose to p ay
themselves in salaries or in di vi d e n d s. There are tax i n centives to reclassify labor inco m e into
more lightly taxed capital income, particularly capital gains. Is the rise of the capital share—
especially at the top—a real phen o m en on or an illu si o n caused by changes in tax avoidance? To
shed light on this issue, the bo t to m panel of Figure 8 depi ct s the average age o f top earners. The
adult population is steadily growing older since the late 1970s. By cont r ast , average age declined
at the top from 1979 to 2000, consistent with the rise of the labor share of top earners and the
notion that the working rich were r ep l a ci n g rentiers. Since 2000, this trend has reverted: top
earners are growing older. The trend break in 2000 exactly mirrors the reversal of the capital
share—lending support to the view that the “worki n g rich” are ind eed playing a sm a l l er role
than they used to at the top of the pyramid.
50
Over the last fifteen years, capital income has been the key driver of the rise o f the top
1% income share. Figure 9 decomposes the top 1% income share into labor and capital. The
labor income of top 1% earners boomed in the 1980s and 1990s, but si n ce the late 1990s it has
declined as a fr a ct i on of natio n al inco m e. Instead , all the increase in the top 1% income share in
recent years owes to an upsurge in capital income, in particular profits from corporate equities.
These results confirm the earlier finding from Piketty and Saez (2003) that the rise in income
concentr at i o n up to the late 1990s was primarily a labor income phenomenon; they are also
consistent with the more recent fi n d i n g by Saez and Zucman (2016) that wealth concentration
has increased sharply since 2000. The rise in wealth inequa l i ty leads to an increase in capital
income concentration, which itself reinforces wealth inequal i ty to the extent that top capital
incomes are saved at a high rate.
5.3 The Role of Taxes and Transfers
About a third of U.S. national income is redistribut ed through taxes, transfers, and public good
spending. How have changes in ta xe s and transfers affected the dynamic of post-tax income?
50
In Appendix Figure S.10, we present another indi c ati on that the rise in the capit al share of income is a
real economic phenomenon. We compute capital income by assuming a fixed rate of return to capital across
the distribution. This procedure neutralizes pot e ntial changes in how labor income is reclassified into capital
income. The results also show a clear rising share of capit al income at the top, although the increase starts
earlier—in the late 1980s rather than in the early 2000s.
27
Taxes. The progressivity of the U.S. tax system has declined significantly over the last decades.
The top panel o f Figure 1 0 shows how effective tax rates var y across th e income distribution.
51
The tax rates we compute take into account all taxes—on individual incomes, payroll, es ta t es,
corporate profits, properties, and sales—whether levied by federal, state, or local governments.
Tax rates are computed as a percentage of pre-tax income. For the Uni t ed States as a whole,
the m acr oeconomic tax rate increased from 8% in 1913 to 30% in t h e late 19 6 0s. Since then, it
has remained at that level. However, effective tax rates have become more compressed across
the in co m e distributio n . In the 1950s, top 1% incom e earners paid 40%-45% of their pre-tax
income in taxes, while bottom 50% earners paid 15-20%. The gap is much smaller t oday: top
earners p ay about 30%-35% of thei r income in taxes, while bottom 50% earners pay around
25%. The effective rat e paid by the top 1% exhibits cyclical variations. During stock market
booms, top 1% income earners realize capital gains; the taxes paid on those gains are included
in the numerator of the effecti ve tax rate but the capital ga i n s themselves are excluded from the
denominator, because pre-tax income (just like national income) excludes capital gains. There
is, however, a downward trend over time. The bulk of the decline owes to the fall of co r porate
and estate taxes. In the 196 0 s, as shown by Appendix Table II-G2, the top 1% paid close t o
20% of its pre-tax income in corporate and estate tax es while it pays only about 10% today.
The 2013 tax reform has partly reverted the long-r u n decline in top tax rates. The 20 1 3 t a x
reform invol ved a sizable increase in top mar gi n a l income tax rates—plus 9.5 points for capital
income and 6.5 points for l abor income, see Saez (2017)—as a result of surtaxes introduced by
the Affordable Care Act and the expirati on of the 2001 Bush tax cuts for top earners. These
increases are the la r ges t hikes in top tax rates since the 19 5 0s, exceeding the 1993 increa ses of
the Clinton administrat i on . Th e effective tax rate paid by top 1% earners has risen about 4
points between 2011 (32%) and 2013 ( 3 6% ) and is now back to its level of t he early 1980s.
52
Although a significant development, i t is worth noting tha t inequality was mu ch lower in the
1980s than today, and that th e long-run decline in corporate and estate tax revenue continues
to exert a downward pressure on effective tax rates at the top.
While tax rates have tended to fa l l for top earners since the 1960s, they have risen for the
bottom 50%. As shown by the bottom panel of Figure 10, this incr eas e essenti a l l y owes to
51
Comprehensive tax rates including all levels of government have not been computed before. Estimates of
Federal (but not State and local) taxes have been produced by the US Congressional Budget Office (2016)
starting in 1979 and by Piketty and Saez (2007) startin g in 1962; no estimates of Federal tax rat e s existed for
the pre-1962 period.
52
The US Congressional Bu dge t Office (2016) also finds an increas e by about 4-5 points in the federal tax rate
of the top 1% from 2011 to 2013.
28
the ri se of payroll taxes. In the 1960s, payroll taxes amounted to 5% of the pre-tax inco m e
of bo t to m 50% earners; today they exceed 10%. In fact, payroll taxes are now much more
important than any other taxes—federal and state—borne by the bottom 50% . In 2014, payrol l
taxes amount to 11.3% of pre-tax income, significantly above the next largest items—federal
and state income taxes, 6.6% of pre-tax income, an d sales taxes, 4.7%.
53
Although payroll
taxes finance transfers—Social Security and Medicare—that go in part to the bottom 50 % ,
their increase contributes to the stagnation of the post-tax income of working-age bott o m 50%
Americans.
Transfers. One major evolu t i o n in the U.S . economy over the last fifty years is the rise of
individualized transfers—monetary, and more import a ntly in-kind transfers. While public g ood
spending has remained constant around 18% of natio n a l income, tr a ns fers—o t h er than Social
Security, disability, and unemployment insurance already included in pre-tax income—have
increased from about 2 % of national income in 1960 to 11% today, see Appendix Figure S. 1 2
and Appendix Table I-S.A11. The two largest transfers are Medicaid (4% of national income
in 2014) and Medicare (3.2 % of national income in 2014); other i m portant transfers includ e
refundable tax credits (0.8% of national income, risin g to 1.3% d u r in g the Great Rec essi o n ) ,
veterans’ benefits (0.6% of national income, twice the level of the 1990s and early 2000s) and
Food Stamps (0.5% of national income).
Individualized transfers tend overall to be targeted to the middle class. The top panel of
Figure 11 shows the ave ra g e transfers received by post-tax income groups, expr esse d as a percent
of t h e average national income in the full adult population.
54
Despite Medicaid and other means-
tested programs which entirely go the bottom 50%, the middle 40% receives larger transfers than
the bot t o m 50% Americans. In 2014, the bo t t om 50% receives the equivalent of 10% of per-a d u l t
national income—less th a n the macro average of 11%—, the middle-class receives more—close
to 16%—and th e top 10% receives less—about 8%. As shown by Appendix Figure S.13, there is
a similar inverted U- sh a ped relationship between post-tax income and transfers r ecei ved when
including Social Secur i ty benefits in transfers: the average transfer th en amounts to 16.6% of
average national inc om e, and close to 25% of average national income for mi dd l e-cl a ss adults.
Transfers have p l ayed a key role in enabling middle-class income to grow. As shown by the
53
In keeping with the national accounts conventions, we treat the non-refundable portion of tax credits and
tax deductions as negative taxes, but the refundable portion of tax credits as a transf er . As a result, nobody
can have negative income taxes.
54
We choose this representation for transfers because individualized transfer s are fair l y close t o a fixed amount
per individual, in contrast to taxes which are fairly close to being proportional to pre-tax income.
29
bottom panel of Figure 11, without transfer s average income for the middle 40% would not have
grown at all from 1999 to 2014. In actual fact it grew 10%, thanks to an increase of 37% in
transfers received excludi n g Social Security. Tax credi ts played a particularly important role
during the Great Recessi o n . With ou t transfers the average income of the middle-cl a ss would
have fallen by 10% between 2007 and 2009; thanks to transfers the decline was limited to 4%.
By contrast, given the collapse in their pre-tax i n c om e, transfers have not bee n sufficient to
enable bottom 50% incomes to grow significantly.
6 Comparison w it h Previous Estimates
6.1 Comparison with top fiscal income shares
Our new distribution a l national accounts confirm the rise of income concentration seen in tax
data. Figure 12 compares our top 10% pre-tax income share to the one esti m a t ed by Piketty
and Saez (2003, series updated to 2015) based on fiscal income. Th er e is a similar U-shaped
evoluti o n of income concentration over the last century. Rising inequality is not an illusion of
tax data: when taking a comprehensive and consistent view of income over the long run, the
upsurge of income at the top appears to be a real economic phenomenon. Th e re are, however,
differences between our top pre-tax income shares and Piketty and Saez’s ( 20 0 3) top fiscal
income shares.
First, the inequa l i ty of pre-tax inco m e is less volatile than that of fiscal income. In fiscal
income statistics, corporate taxes ar e excluded and the retained earnings of corporations are
implicitly proxied by realized capital gains, which are volatile d u e to large short-run swings in
equity values. By contrast, pre-tax income statistics fully allocate corporate profits (t h e sum
of retained earnings, dividend payouts, and corporate taxes) each year to the persons to which
they accrue. As a result, while top fiscal inc om e shares are erratic around the Tax Reform
Act of 1986—in large pa rt due to the realization of capital gains in 1986 before the increase in
capital gains tax rates in 1987—as well as during stock market booms, our new pre-tax national
income shares do not exhibit large year-t o- year variation.
Second, and more im po r t antly, the similarity between th e share of pre-tax national income
going to the top 10% adults and Piketty and Saez’s (2003) share of fiscal income going to the
top 10% tax un i t s masks two discrepancies that go in opposite direction. There is general l y
more inequality in pre-tax income than in fiscal income, but less inequality among (equal-split)
adults than among tax units. These two effects offset each other in 1980. But the “national
30
income vs. fi sc al income” effect dominated before, while the “equal-split adult s vs. tax unit”
effect has dominated since then.
Pre-tax income is generally more conc entrated than fi sca l income because most pre-tax
capital income is n o t taxable—and capital income tends to be concentrated at the top. As the
bottom panel of Figure 12 shows, the un-equal i zi n g effect of ta x- ex em p t capital income was
particularly large in the 1950s and 1960s, when undistributed corporat e profits were hi g h . In
those years, top 10% t ax units earned about 33% of fiscal income but as much as 38% of all
pre-tax income. The gap between pre-tax and fiscal top i n com e shares has fallen since the 1960s,
for two reasons. First, the type of capit al in com e that is tax- ex emp t ha s changed over time.
Since the 1970s, a large and growing fraction of tax-exempt cap i t al income has been th e flow
of interest and dividends paid to pensi on funds. This form of capital income is mor e equally
distributed than corporate retained earnings, so accounting for it does not increase inequality
as much . Second, a growing fraction of labor income—employee fringe benefits—goes untaxed,
and this i n c om e is more equally distributed tha n taxable income. As a result, the top 10% tax
units earn about 50% of b o t h fiscal and pre-tax income today.
The second difference with the Piketty and Saez (2003) series is the unit of observation. In
our benchmark series, we compute income inequ al i ty across adults with income equally spli t
between married spouses, in contrast to Piketty and Saez (2003) who compute inequality across
tax units. A tax unit is either a single person aged 20 or above or a married couple, in both
cases with children dependents if any. As shown by Appen d i x Figure S.15b, there is always
less inequality across equal-s p l i t adults than across tax units, because the equalizing effect
of split t i n g income 50/50 among ma r ri e d couples dominates the often un-equaliz i n g effect of
moving from tax units to individuals.
55
In our view, statistics based on equal-split adults, tax units, or individualized adults all
have their merits and shed valuable light on income concentration and its evolution. There
is a long tradition of computing inequality across households, which are conceptually close to
tax unit s.
56
However, because the size of households changes over time, inequality between
households can rise or fall for pur el y demographic reasons. In the United States, the number
of households has been growing faster than the number of adults over the last deca d es, be cau se
of the decline of marr i a ge and the rise of sin gl e- h ea d ed households. Computing inequality
55
A r el at ed difference is that Piketty and Saez (2003) series use the total number of famili e s based on CPS
data which exclude the institutionalized population while our estimates are b ase d on the full adult population.
56
A household can include several tax units like two adult roommates sharing me al s, or a grandparent liv ing
with her kid and grandkids (see US Cens us Bureau, 2016 for the exact definition of households).
31
across equal-split adults neutrali zes this demogra p h i c trend and, as Appendix Figure S.15b
shows, leads to a smaller increase in inequality tha n computing inequality a cr oss tax units. To
compare inequal i ty over time, using the equal-spli t adult as unit of observation is therefore a
meaningful benchmark, as it abstracts from confoun d i n g trends in h o u seh o l d size and gen d er
inequality. There is no silver bullet, however. To measure the inequality of living standard
in the cross-section, one might want to use the h ou s eh ol d unit, maybe with adjustments to
capture economies of scale within the househol d as done for example in the US Congressional
Budget Office (2016) official statistics.
57
To measure the inequality of monetary power, one
might favor fully individualized series—where each spouse is assigned her own income—such
as those discussed in Section 5.1. None of these approaches alone offers a com p re h en si ve view;
all prov i d e valuable vantage points on the cur re nt evolutions of in co m e i n eq ua l i ty and can be
studied using our distributional national a cco u nts.
6.2 Growth for the bottom 90%
The Piketty and Saez (2003) fiscal in com e data have sometimes been used to study the distribu-
tion of economic growth (see e.g., Saez, 2008). As we have seen , however, the top 10% income
share has increased less than estimat ed by Piketty and Saez (2003). The co n seq u en ce is that
there has been more growth for the bot t om 90% since 1980 than what fiscal data suggest—
although still not much. The top panel of Figu re 1 3 s h ows the growth performance o f t h e
bottom 90%. It has been meager since 1980: while average income in the United Sta t es h a s
grown 1.4% a year from 1 980 to 2014, bottom 90% pre-tax income has grown 0.8% . Th i s stands
in contrast to the period from 1946 to 1980, when bottom 90% income grew at the sa m e rate
as average income, abou t 2.0% a year.
58
Modest as it is, bottom 90% pre-tax income growth
is significantly greater than that estimated using the Piketty and Saez (2003) data, according
to which average bottom 90 % incomes has declined since 1980, by 0.1% a yea r . The real in-
come figures from Piketty and Saez (2003) u n d er - est i m at e the growth of bottom 90% incomes
and exaggerate th e share of growth going to top groups. We hop e our new series wil l put the
57
Equal-split se ri e s under-estimate economies of scale wi t h i n the household. John who earns $10,000 gets the
same income as Felix and Maria who as a couple earn $20,000 in total, while in reality John probably has a lower
living standards due to economies of scale—i t may be harder for him, for instance, to pay his rent. Household
(or tax-unit)-bas ed series, i n contrast, over-estimate economi es of scale, as Felix and Maria count as one unit,
just as Felix. The right equivalence scale probably lies in between the tax unit and the equal-s pl i t adult.
58
The bot t om 90% has grown slightly faster post-tax, at 1.0% per year since 1980—which is still substantially
less than the 1.4% growth rate for the full population; see Appendix Figure S.16. Redistribution toward the
bottom 90% has in cr eas ed over time: in the post-Wor l d War II decades, bottom 90% incomes were on l y about
3% higher post-tax than pre-tax, while they are 13% higher today. But this redistri b u ti on has only offset about
one third of the growt h gap between the bottom 90% an d the average since 1980.
32
discussion of the di s tr i b u t i o n of income growth on a stronger footing.
There are three reasons why middle-class growth has been stronger than in the Piketty and
Saez (2003) series. First, the inequality literature—in c l u di n g Piketty and Saez (2003)—deflates
incomes by the consumer price index (CPI), while we use the more comprehensive and accurate
national income price index. It is well known that the CPI tends to over-state in fl a t i on , in
particular because it is not chained—contrary to the national income price index—h en ce does
not properly account for the substitution bias (Boskin, 1996).
59
The CPI has been growing
0.2% a year faster than the national income deflator since 1980. Second, as we have seen, the
number of tax un i t s has been gr owing faster than the number of adults; this d i vergence has
accelerated since 1980 (+0.3 % a year). To comp u te growth statistics, it makes little sense to
use households as t h e unit of observation: one does not want growth to be affected by changes
in marriage and divorce rates, in particular because it would make cross-country comparis ons
more difficult.
Last, and most importantl y, the tax-exempt income of bottom 90% ear n er s has g r own sig-
nificantly si nce 1980. The bottom panel of Figure 13 decom poses the average income of bottom
90% adul t s earners into taxable labor income, tax-exempt labor income—fringe benefits and
employer payroll taxes—and capital income. Tax-ex em p t l abor income accounted for 13% of
bottom 90% income in 1962; it now accounts for 23%. Capital income has also been on the rise,
from 11% to 15% of average bottom 90% income—all of this increase owes to the rise of imputed
capital income earned on tax-exempt pensi on plans. In fact, since 1980, only tax-exempt labor
income and capital income have been growing for the botto m 90%. The taxab l e labor income
of bottom 90% ear n er s— wh i ch is t h e only form of income th at can be used for the consumption
of good s and non-health services—has not grown at all.
7 Conclusion
In this paper, we have combined tax, survey, and national accounts data to build distribu-
tional national accounts for the United States since 1913. Our series capture 100% of nationa l
income. They can be used to provide decompositions of growth by income groups consistent
with macroeconomic growth; to contrast pre-tax and post-tax income; to compar e in e qu a l i ty
between equal-split adults, i n d i v i d u a l s, and tax units; to jointly study income and wealth; and
to simulate the g r owth and distributional impacts of tax and transfer reforms, among other
59
Piketty and Saez (2003) and official Census Bureau statis t ic s (US Census Bureau, 2016) use the CPI-U-RS
series which incorporate some of the better current methods to esti mat e the CPI and apply them retrospectively
back to 1978. However the CPI-U-RS is not chained.
33
things. As inequality has become a key issue in the public debate in the United States, we feel
that such distr i b u t i o n al na t i on a l accou nts are a needed tool to bett er mo n i to r econ om i c growth
and its distribution. We see three main avenues for future research.
First, our dataset should be seen as a prototype to be further developed and improved upon—
just like the national accounts themselves, including the computation of GDP, are regularly
improved. Looking forward, our assumptions and im p u t at i o n s coul d be bettered by drawing on
new knowledge on the incidence of taxes and transfers and by leverag i n g new and better data.
For example, tax d at a after 2013 prov i d e direct in fo rm a t i on at the micro-level on the value
of employee health insura n ce benefits. Li ke the national a cco u nts, we see our distributional
national accounts as work in constant evolution. Our hope is that our prototype distributional
national accounts will ultimately be taken over , r efi n ed, p u b l i sh ed , an d regularly imp r oved upo n
by government statistical agencies.
Second, distributi o n al national accou nts can be used to compare income across co u ntries on
a consistent basis. The same methodology as the one pioneered in this paper is currently being
applied to other co u ntries. Our long-term goal is to create distr i b u t i o n al national accounts
for as many count r i es as possible and to produce global distr i b u t i o n s of income an d wealth
consistent with global income a n d wealth account s.
60
As an illustration, Fi gu r e 14 compares the
average bottom 50 per cent pre-tax national income in the United States to the average bottom
50 per cent pre-tax income in France estimated by Garbinti, Goupille, and Piketty (2016) using
similar methods. In sharp contrast with the United States, in France the average pre-tax income
of the bottom 50 percent grew by 32 percent from 1980 to 2014 (after adjusting for infl a t i on ) ,
at approximately the same rate as national income per adult. While average income for the
bottom half of the distribution was 11 percent lower in Fran ce than in t h e United States in 1980,
is is now 16 percent higher. The bottom half makes more in France than in the United States
even though average income per adult is 35 percent lower in France (partly due to differences in
standard wor ki n g ho u r s in the two countries).
61
The divergin g tren d s in the growth of bot t om
50 percent incom es across France and th e United States—two advanced economies subject to
the same for ces of technological progress and globalization—suggests that domestic policies play
an important role for the dynamic of income inequality. In the United States, the stagnation
of bottom 50 percent incomes and the upsurge in the top 1 percent coincided with reduced
60
All the results wil l be made available online on the World Wealth and Income Database (WID.world), see
http://www.wid.world/.
61
Since the welfare state is more generous in France, the gap between the bottom 50 percent of income earners
in France an d the United States would probably be even greater after taxes and transfe r s. Garbinti, Gou p il l e,
and Piketty (2016) have not estimated post-tax income s er ie s yet.
34
progressive taxation, widespread deregulati on —p a r t i cu l ar l y in the fin a n ci a l sector—, weakened
unions, and an er o si o n of the federal minimum wage.
Third, it would be valuable to produ c e State and local distributional accounts within the
United States. This would be particularly valuab l e at a time where discrepancies across States
in terms of econ omi c growth an d opportunity have come to the forefront of the poli t i ca l debate.
Since 1979, the intern al tax data have precise geographical indicators and are large en o u gh
to study outcomes at the state or regional level. Our approach naturally lends itself to th e
definition of national income across geographical units by simply con s i d er i n g the individual
national inco m e of residents in each geographical unit.
62
Starting in 1996, the population-
wide tax data could be leveraged to construct measures of national i n co m e at an even finer
geographical level, such as the county o r the metropolitan statistical area.
62
US National accounts provide measures of GDP, personal consumption expenditure, and personal income
(but not national income) at the state level (see US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis,
2016).
References
Alvaredo, Facundo , Anthony Atkinson, Thomas Piketty, Emmanuel Saez, and Gabriel
Zucman. 2011-present. The World Wealth and Income Database. online at http://www.wid.
world.
Alvaredo, Facundo, Anthony Atkinson, Lucas Chancel, Thomas Piketty, and Em-
manuel Saez, and Gabriel Zucman. 2016. “Distributional National Accounts (DINA)
Guidelines: Concepts and Methods used in the World Wealth and Income Data b a se. ” World
Wealth and Income Da t ab a se document on l i n e at http://www.wid.world.
Atkinson, Anthony B. 2005. “Top Incomes in the UK over the 20th Century.” Journal of
the Royal Statistical Society: Ser ies A (Statistics in Society), 168(2): 325–3 4 3.
Atkinson, Antho ny B., Alessandra Cesarico and Sara h Voitchovsky. 2016. “Top
Incomes and the Gend er Divide.” LSE International Inequality Institute Worki n g Paper 5.
Atkinson, Anthony B. and John Micklewright. 1983. “On the Reliability of Income Data
in the Fa m i l y Expen d i t u re Survey,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society, Series A. 146 (1)
33-61.
Atkinson, Anthony B., Lee Rainwater, and Timothy M. Smeeding. 1995. “I n com e
Distribution in OECD Countries,” OECD Soci al Policy Stu d i es , No. 18, Paris.
Atkinson, Anthony, Thomas Piketty, and Emmanuel Saez. 2011. “Top Incomes in the
Long-Run of History”, Journal of Economic Literature, 49(1), 3-71.
Auten, Ger al d and David Splinter. 2016. “Using Tax Data to Measure Income Inequa l -
ity: Effects of Base Broa d en i n g Tax Reform,” U.S. Department of t h e Treasury, Office of Tax
Analysis, unpublished mimeo.
Barnett, G.E. 1936. Two Tracts by Gregory King. (Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press).
Blau, Francinne, Marianne A. Ferber, and Anne E. Winkler. 2014. The Economics of
Women, Men, and Work, Upper Saddle River, NJ: Prentice-Hall, 7th ed.
Blau, Francinne, Lawrence M. Kahn. 2016. The Gender Wage Gap: Extent, Trends, and
Explanations, NBER Working paper No. 21913.
Boskin, Michael. 1996. “Toward A More Accu r at e Measure Of The Cost Of Living”, Report
to the Senate Finance Committee from the Advisory Commission To Study The Consumer Price
Index.
Chiappori, Pierre-Andr´e and Costas Meghir. 2015. “ Intrahousehold Inequality,” Chapter
16, In: Anthony B. Atkinson and Fran¸cois Bourguignon, (Eds.), Handbook of Income Distribu-
tion, Elsevier: Amsterdam, 1369-1418.
Currie, Janet . 2003. “US Food and Nutrition Programs.” In Means-Tested Transfer Programs
in the United States, ed. Robert Moffitt. (Chicago: Uni versity of Chicago Press).
Fesseau, Maryse and Mar ia Liviana Mattonetti . 2013. “Distributional Measures Across
Household Groups in a National Accounts Fra m ework: Resul ts fr o m an Experimental Cr oss -
Country Exer ci s e on Hou s eh ol d Income, Consumption and Saving,” OECD Statistics Working
Papers.
Fesseau, Maryse, Flor ence Wolff, and Maria Liviana Mattonetti. 2013. “A cross
country comparison of household incom e , consumption and wealth between micro sources and
national accounts aggregates,” Working Paper No. 52, Paris: OECD.
36
Finkelstein, Amy, Nathaniel Hendren, and Erzo F.P. Luttmer. 2016. “The Value of
Medicaid: Interpreting Results from th e Oregon Health Insurance Experi m ent”, NBER working
paper No. 21308.
Fixler, D ennis , and David S. Jo hns on. 2014. “Accounting for the Distribution of Income
in the US National Accounts,” in Measuring Economic Stability and Progress, D. Jorgenson, J.
S. Landefeld, and P. Schreyer, eds., (University of Chicago Press: Chicago).
Fixler, Dennis, David Johns o n, Andrew Cra ig , Kevin Furlong. 2015. “A Consistent
Data Series to Evaluate Gr owth and Inequality in the National Accounts,” BEA Working Paper.
Fullerton, Don and Gilbert E. Me tca l f. 2002. “Tax in ci d e n ce,” in: A. J. Auerbach and
M. Feldstein (eds.), Handbook of Public Economics, Volume 4, chapter 26, 1787 -1 87 2 (North-
Holland: Amsterdam).
Furlong, Kevin. 2014. “Distributional Estimates in the US National Ac cou nts: Integrating
Micro an d Macro Data”, Bu re au of Economic Ana l y si s slides online at ftp://ftp.census.
gov/adrm/fesac/2014-06-13_furlong.pdf
Galor, Oded and Joseph Zeira. 1993. “Income Distribution and Macroeconomics,” Review
of Economics Studies, 60( 1 ) , 35-52.
Galor, Oded and Omer Moav. 2006. “Das Human Kapital: A Theory of the Demise of the
Class Structure,” Review of Economic Studies 73, 85–117.
Garbinti, Bertrand, Jonathan Goupille, a nd Thomas Piketty. 2016. “Inequality Dy-
namics in Fr anc e, 1900-2014: Ev i d en c e from Distribut i on a l Nationa l Accounts ( D INA) ” , PSE
Working paper.
Guvenen, Fatih, Greg Kaplan, and Jae Song. 2014. “The Glass Ceiling and The Paper
Floor: Gend er Differences among Top Earners, 1981-2012,” NBER Worki n g Paper No. 20560.
Harberger, Arnold C. 1962. “The Incidence of the Corporation Incom e Tax,” Journal of
Political Economy, 70(3), 215–240.
Karabarbounis, Loukas and Bre nt Neim a n. 2014. “The Global Decline of the Labor
Share.” Quarter ly Journal of Economics 129(1), 61-103.
Katz, Lawrence, and David Autor. 1999. “Changes in the Wage Structure an d Earnings
Inequality,” in Handbook of Labor Economics, O. As h en fel t er and D. Card, eds. (Amsterdam:
North-Holland), Volume 3A.
King, Willford I. 1915. The Wealth and Income of the People of the United States, ( New
York: Macmi l l i an ) .
King, Willfo rd I. 1927 . “Wealth Distribution in the Continental United States at the Close
of 1921”, Journal of the American Statistical Association, 22, 135–15 3 .
King, Willford I. 1930. The National Income and Its Purchasing Power, (New York: National
Bureau of Economic Res ear ch).
Kopczuk, Wojciech, Emmanuel Saez, and Jae Song. 2010, “Ear n i n gs Ineq u al i ty an d
Mobility in the Unit ed States: Evidence from Social S ecu r i ty Data since 1937,” Quarterly
Journal of Economics 125(1), 91–128.
Kuznets, Simon. 1941. National Income and Its Composition, 1919–1938 (New York: Na-
tional Bureau of Eco n om i c Research).
Kuznets, Simon. 1 95 3. Shares of Upper Income Groups in Income and Savings ( New York:
National Bureau of E con o m i c Research).
37
Kuznets, Simon. 1955. “Economic Growth and Income Inequality.” American Economic
Review, 45(1), 1–2 8.
McCully, Clinton. 2014. “Integra ti o n of Micro and Mac ro da t a on Consu m er Inco m e and
Expenditure,” in Measuring Economic Stability and Progress, D. Jorgenson, J. S.Landefeld, and
P. Schreyer, editors, University of Chicago Press, 2014.
Pierce, Brooks . 2001. “Compensat i on Inequality, 1913-1998,” Quarterly Journal of Eco-
nomics 116(4), 1493–1525.
Piketty, Thomas. 2001. Les hauts revenus en France au XXe si`ecle: Inegalit´es et redistribu-
tions 1901–1998. (Paris: Grasset).
Piketty, Thomas. 2003. “Income In e qu a l i ty in France, 1901–1998.” Journal of Political
Economy, 111(5): 1004–1042.
Piketty, Thomas. 2014. Capital in the 21st Century. Ca mbridge: Harvard University Press.
Piketty, Thomas, and Emmanuel Saez. 2003. “Income Inequality in th e United States,
1913-1998,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 118( 1 ) , 1-39.
Piketty, Thomas and Emmanuel Saez. 2007. “How Progressive is the US Federal Tax
System? A Historical and International Perspective,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 21(1),
3-24.
Piketty, Thomas, Emmanuel Sa ez, and Stefanie Stantcheva. 2 0 14 . “Optimal Tax at i o n
of Top Labor Incomes: A Tale of Three Elasticities,” American E conomic J ournal: Economic
Policy 6(1), 230–271.
Piketty, Thomas, and Gabriel Zucman. 2014. “Capital i s Back: Wealth-In co m e Ratios in
Rich Countries, 1700-2 0 10 , ” Quarterly Journal of Economics 129(3), 1255-1310.
Saez, Em ma nuel. 200 8. “Striking It Richer: The Evol u t i o n of Top Incomes in the United
States,” Pathways Magazine, Stanford Center for the Study of Poverty and Inequality, 6-7.
Saez, Emmanuel. 20 16 . “Statistics of Income Tabulations: High Inco mes, Gender, Age,
Earnings Split, and Non-filers.” SOI Working Paper.
Saez, Emmanuel. 2017. “Taxing the Rich More: Preliminary Evidence from the 2013 Tax
Increase,” Tax Polic y and the Economy, ed. Robert Moffitt, (Cambridge: MIT Press), Volume
31.
Saez, Emmanuel and Gabriel Z ucma n. 2016 . “Wea l t h I n eq u al i ty in the Uni te d St a te s si n ce
1913: Evidence from Capitalized Income Tax D a t a, ” Quarterly Journal of Economics 131(2),
519-578.
Stiglitz Joseph, Amartya Sen, and Jean-Paul Fitoussi. 2009. Report by the Commission
on the Measurement of Economic Performance and Social Progress, INSEE France, online at
www.stiglitz-sen-fitoussi.fr.
United Nations. 2009. “System of National Accounts 2008,” European Communities, Inter-
national Monetary Fun d , Organisation for Economic Co-operation and Development, United
Nations and World Bank . online at http://unstats.un.org/unsd/nationalaccount/docs/
SNA2008.pdf
US Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System. 2014. “Z.1 Financial Accounts
of the United States , Fourth Quarter 2013.” downloaded, March 6, 2014.
US C ens us Bureau. 2016. “Income and Poverty in the United States: 2015 Current Popula-
tion Reports”, Publication P60-252, US Census Bureau, Washington DC.
38
US Congressional Budget Office. 2016 . “The Distribution of Household Income and Fed er al
Taxes, 2013”, US Congr es si on a l Budget Office report, Washin g t on DC.
US Department of Commerce, Bureau of Economic Analysis. 2016. National Income
and Product Accounts of the United States, 1929-2015, (Washington, DC).
US Treasury Department, Internal Revenue Service. 1916-present . Statistics of Income:
Individual Income Tax Returns, annual since 1916, Wash i n gt o n , D.C.
Zucman, G abr ie l. 2013. “The Missing Wealth of Natio n s: Are Europe and the US net
Debtors or net Credi t or s? ” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 128(3), 1321-1364.
Zucman, Gabriel. 2014. “Tax Evasion on Offshore Profits and Wealth”, Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 28(4), 121-148.
39
Table 1: The Distribution of National Income in the United States in 2014
Income group
Number of
adults
Average
income
Income share
Average
income
Income share
Average
income
Income share
Full Population 234,400,000 $64,600 100% $48,900 100% $64,600 100%
Bottom 50% 117,200,000 $16,200 12.5% $17,700 18.1% $25,000 19.4%
Middle 40% 93,760,000 $65,400 40.5% $50,300 41.1% $67,200 41.6%
Top 10%
23,440,000 $304,000 47.0% $200,000 40.9% $252,000 39.0%
Top 1%
Top 0.1%
Top 0.01%
23,440 $28,100,000 4.4% $17,200,000 3.5% $20,300,000 3.1%
Top 0.001% 2,344 $122,000,000 1.9% $75,000,000 1.5% $88,700,000 1.4%
Pre-tax national income
Post-tax national income
Post-tax disposable income
Notes: This table reports statistics on the income distribution in the United States i n 2014 for three income concepts: (1) pre-tax national income, ( 2)
post-tax disposable income, and (3) post-tax national income. Pre-tax and post-tax national income match national income. Post-tax disposable income
excludes in-kind government transfers (medicare, medicaid, etc.), publ i c goods consumption (defense, education, etc.), and the government deficit. The
unit is the adult individual (aged 20 or above). Income is split equally among spouses. Fract il e s are d efi ne d relative t o the total number of adults in th e
population. Pre-tax national incom e fractiles are ranked by pre-tax national income, post-tax disposable income f r act i l es are ranked by post-tax disposable
income, and post-tax national income fractiles are ranked by post-tax nation al income. Hence, the three s et s of fractiles do not represe nt exactly the same
groups of individuals due to re-ranking when switching from one income definition to another.
40
Table 2: The Growt h of National Income in the United States since World War II
Income group 1980-2014 1946-1980 1980-2014 1946-1980
Full Population 61% 95% 61% 95%
Bottom 50% 1% 102% 21% 130%
Middle 40% 42% 105% 49% 98%
Top 10% 121% 79% 113% 69%
Top 1% 205% 47% 194% 58%
Top 0.1% 321% 54% 299% 104%
Top 0.01% 454% 75% 424% 201%
Top 0.001% 636% 57% 617% 163%
Pre-tax income growth Post-tax income growth
Notes: The table displays the cumulative real growth rates of pre-tax and post-tax national income per adult over two 34 years period: 1980 to 2014 and
1946 to 1980. Pre-tax and post-tax national in come match national incom e. The unit is the adult individual (aged 20 or above). Fractiles are defined
relative to t h e total number of adults in the populati on. Income is split equally among spouses. Pr e-t ax national income fractiles are ranked by pre-tax
national income while p ost -t ax national income fractiles are ranked by post-tax nati onal income.
41
Figure 1: From Taxable Income to National In co m e
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
1916
1920
1924
1928
1932
1936
1940
1944
1948
1952
1956
1960
1964
1968
1972
1976
1980
1984
1988
1992
1996
2000
2004
2008
2012
% of national income
From taxable to total labor income
Wages and self-employment income
on tax returns
Employer fringe benefits &
payroll taxes
Non-filers
Tax evasion & other
Source: Appendix Table I-S.A8b.
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
1916
1920
1924
1928
1932
1936
1940
1944
1948
1952
1956
1960
1964
1968
1972
1976
1980
1984
1988
1992
1996
2000
2004
2008
2012
% of national income
From taxable to total capital income
Didivends, interest, rents & profits reported on tax returns
Imputed rents + property tax
Retained earnings
Income paid to pensions &
insurance
Non-filers &
other
Corporate income tax
Source: Appendix Table I-S.A8.
Notes: The top panel decomposes total labor income into (i) taxable labor income reported on individual income tax returns
(taxable wages and the labor share—assumed to be 70%—of reported non-corporate business income); (ii) ta x- ex emp t employee
fringe benefits (health and pension contributions) and the employer share of payroll taxes; (iii) wages and labor share of non-
corporate business income earned by non-filers; (iv) tax evasion (the labor share of n on-c orporate business incomes that evade
taxes) and other discrepancies. The bottom panel decomposes total capital income into (i) capital income reported on tax returns
(dividends, interest, rents, royalties, and the capital share of reported non-corporate business income); (ii) imputed rents net of
mortgage inte rest payments plus residential property taxes; (iii) capital income paid to pensions and insurance funds; (iv) corporate
income tax; (v) corporate retained earnings; (vi) tax evasion, non-filers, non-mortgage interest and other discrepancies. Business
taxes are allocated proportionally to ea ch category of capital income. In both panels, sales taxes are a llocated proportionally t o
each category of income, and the denominator is personal factor income as defined in Appendix Table I-A4, which is very close to
national income.
Figure 2: Top Income Shares
25%
30%
35%
40%
45%
50%
1917
1922
1927
1932
1937
1942
1947
1952
1957
1962
1967
1972
1977
1982
1987
1992
1997
2002
2007
2012
2017
% of national income
Top 10% national income share: pre-tax vs. post-tax
Pre-tax
Post-tax
Source: Appendix Tables II-B1 and II-C1
5%
10%
15%
20%
1913
1918
1923
1928
1933
1938
1943
1948
1953
1958
1963
1968
1973
1978
1983
1988
1993
1998
2003
2008
2013
% of national income
Top 1% national income share: pre-tax vs. post-tax
Pre-tax
Post-tax
Source: Appendix Tables II-B1 and II-C1
Notes: The figure displays the share of national income pre-tax and post-tax going to the top 10% adults from
1917 to 2014 (top panel) and to the t op 1% adults from 1913 to 2014 (bottom panel). Adults are all US residents
aged 20 and above. Incomes withi n married couples are equally split. Pre-tax national income is factor income
after the operation of the public and private pension systems and unemployment insurance system. Post-tax
national income is defined as pre-tax income minus all taxes plus all government transfers and spending (federal,
state, and local). Both p re -t ax and post-tax national income aggregate to national i nc ome.
43
Figure 3: Pre-tax vs. Post-tax Bottom 50% Incomes and Shares
10%
15%
20%
25%
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
2014
% of national income
Bottom 50% national income share: pre-tax vs. post-tax
Pre-tax
Post-tax
Source: Appendix Tables II-B1 and II-C1
0
5,000
10,000
15,000
20,000
25,000
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
2014
Average income in constant 2014 $
Real income of bottom 50%:
pre-tax vs. post-tax
Source: Appendix Tables II-B7, II-C7 and II-C3c.
Post-tax
Post-tax,
excl. health transfers
Pre-tax
Post-tax disposable
Notes: The top panel figure depicts the bottom 50% adult income shares pre-tax and post-tax since 1962. The
unit is the individual ad ul t and incomes within married coupl es are split equally. The bottom panel depicts
the bott om 50% average real income per adult for four income definitions: (a) pre-tax national income, (b)
post-tax disposable income (subtracting taxes, adding cash transfers but not in-kind transfers and collecti ve
public expenditures), (c) post-tax national income (adding all transfer s and collective public expenditu r es minus
the government deficit), (d) post-tax national income but excluding Medicare and Medicaid benefits.
44
Figure 4: Bottom 50% Real Incomes by Age Groups
0
5,000
10,000
15,000
20,000
25,000
1979
1983
1987
1991
1995
1999
2003
2007
2011
2015
Average income in constant 2014 $
Real pre-tax income of bottom 50%, by age group
Source: Appendix Tables II-B7 and II-B7b.
All age
20-45 years old
45-65 years old
>65 years old
0
5,000
10,000
15,000
20,000
25,000
30,000
35,000
1979
1983
1987
1991
1995
1999
2003
2007
2011
2015
Average income in constant 2014 $
Real post-tax income of bottom 50%, by age group
Source: Appendix Tables II-C7, II-C7b and II-C7d.
All
20-45 years old
45-65 years old
65+ years old
20-45 years old,
disposable
Notes: This figure depicts the bottom 50% real incomes per adult by age groups. The bottom 50% is defined
within each of the th r ee age groups, 20-44, 45-64, and 65+. The top panel figure d ep ic t s real incomes on a
pre-tax basis while the bottom panel figure depicts real incomes on a post-tax basis. Pre-tax national income is
after the operation of pension and unemployment insurance systems. Post-tax national income is after all taxes
and transfer. Post-tax disposable income excludes in-kind transfers, collective consumption expenditure, and
the government deficit. The unit is the individual adult and incomes wit hi n married couples are split equal ly.
Figure 5: Bottom 50% vs. Top 1%
10%
12%
14%
16%
18%
20%
22%
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
2014
% of national income
Pre-tax national income share: top 1% vs. bottom 50%
Bottom 50%
Top 1%
Source: Appendix Table II-B1
0
7,500
15,000
22,500
30,000
37,500
45,000
52,500
0
200,000
400,000
600,000
800,000
1,000,000
1,200,000
1,400,000
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
2014
Bottom 50% real average pre-tax income (2014$)
Top 1% real average pre-tax income (2014$)
Real average pre-tax income of bottom 50% and top 1% adults
Source: Appendix Tables II-B7 and II-B10
1980: Top 1%
= $428,000
1980: Bottom 50%
= $16,000
2014:Top 1% = $1,305,000
2014: Bottom 50%
= $16,200
Notes: The figure contrasts the evolution of the top 1% vs. the bottom 50%. The top panel plots the top 1%
pre-tax national income share and the bottom 50% pre-tax national income share since 1962. The bottom panel
plots t h e top 1% real average pre-tax national income (on the left y-axi s) and the bottom 50% r eal average
pre-tax national income (on the right x-axis). The unit is the individual adult and incomes within married
couples are split eq ual l y.
Figure 6: The Role of Within Couple Inequali ty and the Decline of the Gender Gap
30%
35%
40%
45%
50%
55%
1917
1922
1927
1932
1937
1942
1947
1952
1957
1962
1967
1972
1977
1982
1987
1992
1997
2002
2007
2012
2017
% of national income
Top 10% pre-tax income share: equal-split vs. individuals
Pre-tax income per adult
(individuals)
Source: Appendix Table II-B9.
Pre-tax income per adult
(equal split)
100%
150%
200%
250%
300%
350%
400%
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
2014
Average pre-tax labor income of
men aged 20-64 / women aged 20-64
Source: Appendix Table II-F1.
Notes: The top panel depicts the top 10% adults pre-tax national inc ome share with two definitions of income:
(a) e qu al split of income within married couples (our benchmark series), (b) split of factor labor income on an
individual basis within c oupl e s (capital income, pension benefits and other benefits remai n split equally). The
bottom panel depicts the average pre-tax labor income of working-age men (aged 20 to 64, including men earning
zero pre-tax labor income) divided by the average pre-t ax labor income of working-age women (aged 20 to 64,
including women earn in g zero pre -t ax labor income). Pre-tax labor income is factor labor income plus pensions,
Social Security, and unemployment insurance benefits, minus the cor r esponding contributions. Pensions and
Social Security benefits are spli t 50/50 between spouses.
Figure 7: Gender Gaps Across the Distribution
0
5,000
10,000
15,000
20,000
25,000
30,000
35,000
40,000
45,000
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
2014
Real median pre-tax income ($2014)
Median pre-tax labor income:
working-age men vs. working-age women
Source: Appendix Table II-B13.
Working-age men
Working-age women
Working age adults
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
35%
40%
45%
50%
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
2014
Share of women in the employed population,
by fractile of labor income
Source: Appendix Table II-F1.
Top 10%
Top 0.1%
Top 1%
All
Notes: The top panel shows the median pre-tax labor income among all working-age adults (20 to 64), m en ,
and women. Pre-t ax labor income includes pensions, Social Se cu r ity, and unemployment insurance benefits and
exclude the corresponding contributions. The bottom panel depicts t h e share of women in various groups of the
distribution of factor labor income. Factor labor in com e excludes pensions, Social Security, and unemployment
insurance benefits and is gross of the corresponding contributions. The groups are defined relative to the full
population of adults with positive factor labor income (either from salaried or non-salar i ed work).
Figure 8: Capital Share and Age in Top Income Groups
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
1913
1923
1933
1943
1953
1963
1973
1983
1993
2003
2013
The share of capital in pre-tax income
Top 0.1%
Top 1%
Top 10%
All
Bottom 90%
Source: Appendix Table II-B2d.
40
42
44
46
48
50
52
54
56
58
1979
1982
1985
1988
1991
1994
1997
2000
2003
2006
2009
2012
2015
Age
Average age by pre-tax income group
Top 0.1%
Top 1%
Top 10%
Average age in the adult population
Source: Appendix Table II-F2.
Notes: The top panel depicts the share of capital income in the pr e-t ax national income of various income groups:
(i) full adult population, (ii) top 10% incomes, (iii) top 1% incomes, (iv) top .1% incomes. Total pre-tax income
is the sum of capital income and labor income so the chart can also be read symmetrically from the top x-axis
line as the fraction of labor income in top groups. The bottom panel depicts the average age in various income
groups: (i) full adult population, (ii) top 10% incomes, (iii) top 1% incomes, (iv) top .1% incomes.
49
Figure 9: Labor and Capital Income of Top 1% Earners
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
1913
1918
1923
1928
1933
1938
1943
1948
1953
1958
1963
1968
1973
1978
1983
1988
1993
1998
2003
2008
2013
% of national income
Pre-tax labor income of top 1% adult income earners
Compensation of
employees
Labor component of mixed income
Source: Appendix Table II-B2b.
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
14%
1913
1918
1923
1928
1933
1938
1943
1948
1953
1958
1963
1968
1973
1978
1983
1988
1993
1998
2003
2008
2013
% of national income
Pre-tax capital income of top 1% adult income earners
Housing rents
Noncorporate profits
Interest
Income from equity
Interest and dividends paid to
pension plans
Source: Appendix Table II-B2b
Notes: The figure depicts labor income of the top 1% of pre-tax national income earners as a share of aggregate
national income (t op panel) and capital income of t he top 1% as a share of aggregate national income (bottom
panel). The sum of these two series is the top 1% income share depicted in Figure 2 (bottom-panel). Labor
income is also decomposed into employee compensation and labor income fr om non corporate business profits.
Capital income is decomposed into housing rents (net of mortgages), non-corporate profits, corporate profits,
net interest, and profit s and interests paid to pension and insurance fund s.
50
Figure 10: Average Tax Rates Across the Distribution
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
35%
40%
45%
1913
1918
1923
1928
1933
1938
1943
1948
1953
1958
1963
1968
1973
1978
1983
1988
1993
1998
2003
2008
2013
% of pre-tax income
Average tax rates by pre-tax income group
Source: Appendix Table II-G1.
All
Bottom 50%
Top 1%
0%
5%
10%
15%
20%
25%
30%
1913
1918
1923
1928
1933
1938
1943
1948
1953
1958
1963
1968
1973
1978
1983
1988
1993
1998
2003
2008
2013
% of bottom 50% pre-tax income
Taxes paid by the bottom 50%
Capital taxes
Sales taxes
Individual income taxes
Payroll taxes
Source: Appendix Table II-G2
Notes: The top panel depicts the macroeconomic tax rate (total taxes to national income), and the average tax
rate of the top 1% and bottom 50% pre-tax national income earners, with i nc ome equally split among spouses.
Taxes include all forms of taxes at the federal , state, and local level. Tax rates are expresse d as a fraction of
pre-tax income. The bottom panel decomposes the taxes paid by the bottom 50%. Capi t al taxes include the
fraction of corporate taxes, property taxes, and estate tax e s that fall on the bottom 50%.
51
Figure 11: Individualize d Transfers Excluding Social Security
0%
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
14%
16%
1960
1965
1970
1975
1980
1985
1990
1995
2000
2005
2010
2015
% of average national income
Average individualized transfer by post-tax income group
(excluding Social Security)
Source: Appendix Table II-G4.
Middle 40%
(P50-P90)
Bot 50%
Top 10%
All
0
10,000
20,000
30,000
40,000
50,000
60,000
70,000
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
2014
Average income in constant 2014 dollars
Real income of the middle 40%:
the role of transfers
Source: Appendix Table II-C3b.
Post-tax income excluding transfers
Post-tax income
Transfers
Notes: The top panel depic t s average individualized transfers received by post-tax national income groups,
expressed as a percent of the average national income in the full adult population. The bottom panel depicts the
average post-tax income of the middle 40% (top 50% excluding the top 10%), including and excluding transfers.
52
Figure 12: Comparison with top fiscal income shares
30%
35%
40%
45%
50%
1917
1922
1927
1932
1937
1942
1947
1952
1957
1962
1967
1972
1977
1982
1987
1992
1997
2002
2007
2012
Top 10% income share: comparison of estimates
Fiscal income per tax unit (Piketty-Saez)
Pre-tax income per adult
Source: Appendix Table II-B1 and Piketty and Saez (2003, updated to 2014).
30%
35%
40%
45%
50%
1917
1922
1927
1932
1937
1942
1947
1952
1957
1962
1967
1972
1977
1982
1987
1992
1997
2002
2007
2012
Top 10% income share: fiscal income vs. pre-tax income
Pre-tax income per tax unit
Source: Appendix Tables II-B9 and Piketty and Saez (2003, updated to 2014)
Missing
income
Fiscal income per tax unit (Piketty-Saez)
Notes: The top panel compares our benchmar k estimates of the share of pre-tax national income earned by top
10% adults (with income equally split betwe en spouses) to the share of fiscal income earned by top 10% tax
units estimated by Piketty and Saez (2003, updated t o 2014). The bottom panel compares the share of pr e- tax
national income earned by top 10% tax units to the share of fiscal income earned by top 10% tax units estimated
by Piketty and Saez (2003, updated to 2014). The sec ond panel uses the same tax units for both ser i es and
hence captures the eff ect of missing income in fiscal income on the top 10% income sh ar e.
53
Figure 13: Growth for the bottom 90%
0
10,000
20,000
30,000
40,000
50,000
60,000
70,000
1946
1950
1954
1958
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
2014
Average income in constant 2014 dollars
Bottom 90% income growth: Pre-tax income vs. fiscal income
National income per adult
Bottom 90% fiscal income per tax unit (Piketty-Saez)
Bottom 90% pre-tax income per adult
Source: Appendix Table II-B3 and Piketty and Saez (2003, updated to 2014)
+2.0%
+1.8%
+1.4%
+0.8%
+2.1%
-0.1%
0
5,000
10,000
15,000
20,000
25,000
30,000
35,000
40,000
1962
1967
1972
1977
1982
1987
1992
1997
2002
2007
2012
Average income in constant 2014$
Average pre-tax income of the bottom 90%
Taxable labor income
Capital income
Tax-exempt labor income
Source: Appendix Table II-B2e
Notes: The top panel compares (i) the average real pre-tax national income of bottom 90% adults (with income
equally split between spouses), (ii) the average fiscal income of bottom 90% tax un it s as e st i mat ed by Piketty
and Saez (2003, updated to 2014), and (iii) average national income per adult. Bottom 90% pre-tax income
per adult and national income per adult ar e deflated by the nat i on al income deflator, while bottom 90% fiscal
income per tax unit is deflated by the CPI used by Piketty and Saez. The numbers report the real annualized
income growth rate over 1946-1980 and 1980-2014. The bottom panel decomposes the pre-tax national income
of bottom 90% adults (wit h income eq u all y spl i t between spouses) into taxable labor income, tax-exempt labor
income (employee fringe benefits and employer payroll taxes), and capital income.
Figure 14: Bottom 50% Incomes in the US vs. Fran c e
0
2,000
4,000
6,000
8,000
10,000
12,000
14,000
16,000
18,000
20,000
1962
1966
1970
1974
1978
1982
1986
1990
1994
1998
2002
2006
2010
2014
Average income in constant 2014 dollars
Average pre-tax income of bottom 50%
adults: United States
Average pre-tax income of bottom 50%
adults: France
Notes: The figure depicts the average pre-tax national income of the bottom 50% adults from 1962 to 2014 in
the United States and France. The unit is the individual adult and incomes within married couples are split
equally. Series for France are expressed in 2014 US dollars using a Purchasing Power Parity exchange rate of
.819 Euros per US dollar as estimated by the OECD. Estimates for France are from Garbinti, Goupille, and
Piketty (2016).